Halina Ward - Trade, Investment and The Environment (2017, Routledge)
Halina Ward - Trade, Investment and The Environment (2017, Routledge)
Trade, Investment and the Environment
During the financial year 1998–9 the Energy and Environmental
Programme was supported by generous contributions of finance and
technical advice from the following organizations:
Amerada Hess
BG
Blue Circle Industries
British Nuclear Fuels
British Petroleum
Eastern Electricity
ENI
Enron
Esso/Exxon
LASMO
Mitsubishi Fuels
Mobil Services
Osaka Gas
PowerGen
Ruhrgas
Saudi Aramco
Shell
Statoil
Texaco
Tokyo Electric Power
Veba Oil
The Guardian
UK Department for International Development
UK Department for Trade and Industry
ICI
International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development
World Wide Fund For Nature (WWF)
Trade, Investment and the Environment
Proceedings of the Royal Institute of
International Affairs conference
Chatham House, London, October 1998
Copyright © Royal Institute of International Affairs, 2000. Published by Taylor & Francis.
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilised in
any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter
invented, including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval
system, without permission in writing from the publishers.
Notices:
Practitioners and researchers must always rely on their own experience and knowledge in
evaluating and using any information, methods, compounds, or experiments described herein.
In using such information or methods they should be mindful of their own safety and the
safety of others, including parties for whom they have a professional responsibility.
Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered trademarks, and are used only
for identification and explanation without intent to infringe.
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Part I A strategic overview of the debate and the key issues for
the future
Renato Ruggiero............................................................................... 3
Brian Wilson ..................................................................................... 11
Gary P. Sampson .............................................................................. 20
David Wakeford ................................................................................ 24
Tom Burke......................................................................................... 27
John Gummer ................................................................................... 36
Many of the papers look forward too. How can options for addressing
the relationship between trade, environment and investment be designed
so as to move beyond stale adversarial discussions to offer genuinely
‘win–win’ solutions? The varied aspirations for a ‘High Level Meeting’
on trade and sustainable development make thought-provoking read-
ing in the light of the WTO Director General’s two symposia on trade
and environment and trade and development held in March 1999. At
the time of going to press, the 1999 Seattle Ministerial Conference of
the WTO and the beginning of the next ‘Millennium Round’ of trade
negotiations are drawing ever nearer. It is striking that the ideas put
forward in this book on ‘environment in the Millennium Round’ are
as fresh as they were at the time of the Chatham House conference a
year ago.
A number of the papers in this volume have been rearranged from
the order in which they originally appeared, to reflect the core themes
of the authors’ ideas and recommendations. Some have been edited,
revised or updated by their authors, and a small number of the confer-
ence presentations have been omitted from this book to avoid duplica-
tion of authors. Additionally, a conference presentation by Michael
Grubb on trade issues related to the Climate Change Convention, sub-
stantially based as it was on research at Chatham House led by Duncan
Brack, has been omitted; the results of that research are being pub-
lished by RIIA/Earthscan in parallel with this book (Duncan Brack,
with Craig Windram and Michael Grubb, International Trade and Cli-
mate Change Policies).
Part I contains six papers which present a strategic overview of the
key issues, the state of the debate and the big issues for the future.
They include the three keynote papers from the Chatham House con-
ference: by Renato Ruggiero, at the time the Director-General of the
WTO; Brian Wilson MP, then UK minister for trade; and John Gummer
MP, former UK secretary of state for the environment. Part II seeks to
explore some of the main ideas and positions in the rapidly evolving
debate on how to secure ‘win–win’ solutions: how can solutions be
devised that offer everyone, including the environment, more than tra-
ditional competitive bargaining? Part III contains a series of papers that
focus on how to resolve some of the more technical issues as they re-
Preface and acknowledgments ix
Introduction
The politics of the relationship between trade liberalization, foreign
direct investment and environmental protection are as uneasy today as
at any time this decade. But the thinking and analytical work on the
means of ensuring just how trade, investment and environment can be
made mutually supportive have advanced substantially, and there is no
shortage of ideas for resolution of the problems. This book is a guide to
both the politics and the policies as they were when the conference on
Trade, Investment and Environment took place at Chatham House in
October 1998.
The 26 papers included in the book explore, from a variety of per-
spectives, many of the issues in the complex relationship between
trade, environment and investment. Our aim in this introduction is to
provide a summary of the papers themselves, and to make a few short
remarks on the debates surrounding the trade–investment–environ-
ment nexus one year on, as the Millennium Round approaches.
There are three basic focuses around which the extraordinarily com-
plex and interlinked issues addressed in these papers centre. First, there
is ‘protection versus protectionism’. Do powerful trading nations use
trade measures as a way of forcing developing countries to adopt es-
sentially their own world-view? Is the trade and environment debate a
form of ‘eco-colonialism’? From an economic, as well as an environ-
mental, perspective, when does it make sense to link environmental
protection objectives to trade policy?
Second is the relationship between foreign direct investment and the
environment. Do the activities of transnational corporations tend, on bal-
ance, to help or hinder environmental protection? How can transnational
corporations most effectively be regulated in order to maximize their
potential contribution to sustainable development? And what does this
mean for any potential multilateral investment framework?
xviii Editors’ overview
Part I A strategic overview of the debate and key issues for the
future
Part I is a collection of short papers that aim to set the scene for the re-
mainder of the book by identifying the key strands and strategic issues
Editors’ overview xix
Mechanism and in the ILO itself. Similarly, it is not at all clear that the
establishment of a global environment organization would in fact re-
solve trade–environment clashes unless WTO rules were themselves
modified.
Mr Ruggiero’s themes are reflected to some extent in Brian Wilson’s
paper. The then UK Minister for Trade expresses the classical eco-
nomic perspective that trade liberalization helps to ensure that re-
sources are used efficiently, thereby generating the wealth necessary
for development and environmental improvement. It also encourages
the spread of clean technology worldwide. He places a strong empha-
sis on the values of consensus, cooperation and dialogue. He applies
this to the WTO itself, with his reassurance that ‘there is no way of set-
ting aside the WTO rights of member countries against their will …
Nothing will – or can – change without consensus’. But he also stresses
the need for the WTO to shed its reputation for secrecy if dialogue at all
levels is to be fully effective.
Gary Sampson addresses the key opportunities and challenges of the
12 months leading up to the Seattle ministerial conference. The key
challenge, for him, is to find a way of dealing with civil society criti-
cisms of the WTO without damaging its credibility as the body respon-
sible for the rules of the non-discriminatory trading system and the
progressive liberalization of trade in goods and services. He identifies
three types of possible initiatives for the 12 months ahead, according
to the degree of governmental involvement necessary. First, there are
those that can be achieved if there is sufficient informal support for the
Director-General or the Secretariat to undertake them; second, there
are initiatives that require the collective approval of WTO Members,
but not formal rule changes; and finally, there are objectives that can
be achieved only through changes in rules.
Like Mr Wilson, David Wakeford also asserts in his paper that liber-
alization of trade and investment creates wealth that leads to higher en-
vironmental standards and a move towards sustainability. Since trade
and investment liberalization and environmental sustainability are al-
ready mutually supportive, this leaves only the questions of the rate at
which progress is achieved, and the degree of improvement of envi-
ronmental performance. For Dr Wakeford, the source of the belief that
Editors’ overview xxi
taining trade provisions is, he says, probably the least difficult area of
potential dispute to resolve in the WTO.
Magda Shahin’s paper presents an overview of trade and environ-
ment discussions in the WTO from a developing-country perspective.
She questions whether the debate is yet sufficiently mature to allow
negotiations with a view to setting new rules and regulations in the
WTO. Her view on MEAs casts doubt on the idea that this is one of the
least difficult areas for the WTO: even if it is perfectly possible to de-
vise technical solutions to the issues, the political issues none the less
remain highly complex. She emphasizes the importance of ‘positive
measures’ (such as technical and financial assistance), as distinct from
trade measures, in MEAs, and suggests that changes to the rules would
offer an unbalanced approach without a parallel commitment to first
use and enforce such positive measures.
Turning to the Shrimp/Turtle dispute, Dr Shahin notes with approval
the panel report’s condemnation of unilaterally imposed trade-related
environment measures that carry a risk of ‘jeopardizing the multilateral
trading system’. This, she says, reflects a political consensus among
WTO members, with the sole exception of the United States, that uni-
lateral measures should be abandoned. A WTO system based on con-
sensus and cooperation cannot be allowed to ‘adapt to … all kinds of
interests’ by allowing trade policy solutions to be applied unilaterally
in line with what individual WTO members see to be environmental
concerns. Dr Shahin is concerned that the subsequent Appellate Body
report in the Shrimp/Turtle case may have opened up the risk of dam-
aging the multilateral trading system through a too-liberal interpreta-
tion of Article XX(g) of the GATT.
Dr Shahin, like Dr Geradin, discounts the ‘pollution haven’ hypoth-
esis, though she emphasizes that stringent environmental regulations can
have a negative impact on developing-country exports. Echoing Nick
Robins’s paper, she points out that the resources and expertise required
to adapt to new regulations in export markets are frequently not avail-
able to developing-country producers. The related issues of technology
transfer and intellectual property rights are likely to feature high on the
future trade and environment agenda, an agenda that must preserve a
balanced approach, so that the development aspect is not overlooked.
xxviii Editors’ overview
nal aims of the MAI were to develop a framework based on the prin-
ciples of non-discrimination, national treatment and liberalization of
foreign investment. For business, says Dr Ehinger, the main objective
was to raise investor confidence. He acknowledges that a failure to
include NGOs and parliamentarians in the negotiations resulted in
some misunderstandings, but in substance he does not view the MAI
as a failure. The OECD Secretariat’s work remained in line with the
main objectives of the Agreement and the ‘three-anchor’ approach was
an appropriate and effective means of addressing key environmental
aspects of the agreement. As to whether WTO negotiations would be
better, Dr Ehinger stresses that the siting of the MAI in the OECD was
the result of compromise in a debate about whether it was better to
have broader geographical coverage or higher standards. At all times,
the incorporation of an MAI in the WTO remained the ultimate goal.
Pradeep Mehta of the Consumer Unity and Trust Society in India
assesses the relationship between foreign direct investment and the
environment, and the lessons of the MAI negotiations, from a develop-
ing-country NGO perspective. He begins by examining whether the
‘no lowering standards in the area of environment and labour’ anchor
of the MAI’s three-anchor approach was appropriate and adequate. Do
lower standards in developing countries pull in more polluting invest-
ment, or, on the contrary, is it high standards in developed countries
that ‘push’ investors to developing countries? In fact, Mr Mehta be-
lieves that, where the relationship between foreign direct investment
and environment is a negative one, at least some blame needs to be
placed at the door of multinational corporations themselves, not gov-
ernments. He gives a number of examples of situations where multina-
tional corporations have double standards in their operations, applying
different environmental management standards in developing coun-
tries from those that they would have applied at home. The solution, he
says, should lie with the notion that businesses must respect the widely
recognized principle of environmental protection, including the prin-
ciple of maintaining the same standards in their operations worldwide.
A central theme of Mr Mehta’s arguments is the fundamental in-
equity at the heart of the MAI. While its primary target was the resources
and consumer markets of the developing countries, those countries
Editors’ overview xxxv
were never a part of the negotiations, which took place within the
closed club of the OECD. Second, there was no consideration in the
negotiations of the need to ensure a proper balance of the rights of, and
the obligations upon, the investors. Mehta’s conclusion is that it is
questionable whether a multilateral investment framework and new in-
ternational rules are needed at all, given the pace at which foreign di-
rect investment is currently increasing in the absence of such rules.
Nick Mabey of WWF characterizes the opposition to the MAI as a
clash of world views: the economic and the sustainable. He sees the
MAI as a threat to efforts to address the world’s environmental prob-
lems through action at the national or sub-national levels. For him, and
for many others among those opposing the MAI, it would have in-
creased the power of incoming investors, reducing the ability of host
countries to negotiate the best deal. For the future, Mr Mabey believes
that the objective of investment agreements needs to be sustainable
development. There should be more emphasis on positive initiatives
such as the promotion of ethical business through preferential access
to guaranteed loans and trade promotion. In short, if the investment
agenda is to be passed to the WTO, it needs to be fundamentally re-
thought.
It remains to be seen whether negotiators of any genuinely multilat-
eral investment regime are able to move beyond the established con-
cepts offered by the hundreds of bilateral investment agreements al-
ready in place, or to draw a line under the unhappy experience of the
MAI and start afresh. The opening stages of the Millennium Round
will be critical in setting the agenda.
Finally, Part V contains Halina Ward’s summary of the discussion
sections of the Chatham House conference that formed the basis of this
book.
services and investment, shrinking distances and time. And this pro-
cess, in turn, is creating an awareness of interdependence on a plan-
etary scale. Television, fax machines, mobile phones and the Internet
are erasing barriers not only between economies, but between people,
allowing us to see and understand how interconnected we are. There is
a globalization of our consciousness, as well as of our economies. And
this dimension of globalization, more than any other, will prove impos-
sible to slow down or reverse.
The financial crisis has dominated our discussions over the past year,
with its moments of pessimism and moments of renewed hope. It is
clear that this is first and foremost a financial crisis, and the solutions
must be found from within the financial and monetary systems. But it
is now equally clear that continued financial and exchange rate insta-
bility can – and will – have a negative effect on world trade, investment
and development. Declining commodity prices, weakening imports in
the affected countries, excessive export competition in the advanced
markets and the threat of further devaluations – all of these forces are
introducing new uncertainties, new risks and new protectionist pres-
sures into the global economy.
The reality is that the questions raised by the financial crisis go to the
heart of the major challenge of our time: the challenge of global gover-
nance in this complex and interdependent era. Can we maintain a stable
and increasingly borderless global economy, with rising trade, employ-
ment and growth, without a stable global financial and monetary sys-
tem? Will the integration of our economies require a more coordinated
approach to fiscal, monetary, development and environmental poli-
cies, as well as trade policy? Does the logic of globalization force us to
re-examine the global architecture?
A new international consensus will have to develop for improving
the management of the global economy if we are to continue to liberal-
ize markets, and if globalization is to fulfil its promise.
First, we need to open up the international system to wider participa-
tion at the highest level of the decision-making process. This implies
that we must move from a predominantly unilateral leadership to a
more collective leadership – and one with a more balanced share of
responsibility. This does not mean that US leadership is any less impor-
A strategic overview of the debate 5
tant. What it means is that Europe, Japan, the transition regimes and
the developing countries that make up a growing share of the world
economy must be prepared to play their part. The recent G-22 meet-
ings are good initial steps in this direction.
And this in turn means that the nature of international leadership
must change. During the Cold War, leadership was about solidarity,
discipline, the possibility of force in the common defence of our val-
ues. By contrast, leadership in an interdependent world is the art of
cooperation and consensus. It is about recognizing that our national
interests are increasingly global interests, and that our national security
increasingly hinges on the security of others. I do not suggest that the
voice of internationalism is an easy one in the present climate – only
that it is essential in our globally interdependent world.
Second, we need to broaden the scope of the issues that are part of
the international agenda and at the highest level of the system. We can
no longer afford to view issues through a sectoral lens. We need to
look at the challenges we face from a broader perspective, and as
pieces of a larger, interconnected puzzle. Globalization has given rise
to a lengthening list of issues that now cross borders, from environ-
mental standards and development concerns to the distribution of re-
sources, labour standards, health issues, human rights, education,
technological empowerment – even foreign security. More and more,
we are dependent on each other’s financial stability, economic devel-
opment, environmental security and political reform. More and more,
there is pressure to widen the scope of international coordination, and
to define institutions that can bridge the gap between an economic and
technological system that is increasingly global, and a political system
that is still predominantly national.
The recent Shrimp/Turtle appeal in the WTO is the clearest sign yet
that the trading system is fully supportive of policies to protect endan-
gered species or the environment – but that it is up to the environmental
community itself to provide this policy framework, or to implement
the policies without discrimination. It strongly reinforces the grow-
ing need to negotiate global environmental rules and standards – and
to reach a global consensus about environmental issues. And it under-
lines the need to strengthen existing bridges between trade and envi-
ronmental policies, a task that would be made immeasurably easier if
we could also create a house for the environment to help focus and
coordinate our efforts.
This Shrimp/Turtle appeal is extremely important because it clarifies
one essential issue in the debate between the trade community and the
environmental community: that there are no political, economic or le-
gal obstacles to the harmonious development of both environmental
objectives and free trade objectives. And here it is important to put on
the record the conclusions of the Appellate Body in this case:
We wish to underscore what we have not decided in this case. We have not decided
that the protection and preservation of the environment is of no significance to
Members of the WFO. Clearly it is. We have not decided that the sovereign nations
that are Members of the WTO cannot adopt effective measures to protect endan-
gered species, such as sea turtles. Clearly, they can and should. And we have not
decided that sovereign states should not act together bilaterally, plurilaterally or
multilaterally, either within the WTO or other international fora, to protect endan-
gered species or to otherwise protect the environment. Clearly, they should and do.1
This appeal makes it even more impossible to say that trade policy
does not consider environmental issues. It is clear not only that the
trade system takes environmental concerns into account, but – if they
are implemented without discrimination – that these concerns prevail
over free trade objectives.
This is of fundamental importance, because if we want to succeed in
defining our objectives – both the trade community and the environ-
1
United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, para. 185,
WT/DS58/AB/R (12 October 1998).
A strategic overview of the debate 7
2
Newsweek, 12 October, 1998, p. 24C.
8 Renato Ruggiero
Introduction
We are faced by global problems and we need to find global solutions.
We will only achieve this by greater cooperation and dialogue between
the people from all interested groups. We have all begun to understand
better the links between our interests in trade, investment, environ-
ment, development and wider issues.
The UK government is strongly committed to the creation of open
markets around the world, supported by effective multilateral rules.
Free trade benefits developing countries by providing access to over-
seas markets. It brings better quality, more choice and lower prices to
consumers. It stimulates the efficiency and innovation of business.
And, by giving them access to competitively priced components and
services, it allows businesses to profit and grow. Throughout the last
50 years, growth in world trade has constantly outstripped the growth
of GDP. It has been estimated that the Uruguay Round of negotiations
alone when fully implemented will add US$500 billion each year to
world income. We are all more prosperous as a result.
But clearly, there remains much more to be done. There are genuine
benefits, for economic growth, improved living standards and new job
creation across the world, to be gained from further liberalization. Ob-
viously these are difficult times for the world economy. The temptation
is to take the easy populist approach – to try to close domestic markets.
But protectionist measures will get none of us anywhere in the medium
term and must be resisted.
There are other threats to the liberalization agenda, and one of the
most important of these is the belief that free trade must be bad for
the environment. So in the longer term our objectives are to pursue
open markets in a way that recognizes that there are genuine con-
cerns about sustaining the environment and therefore that we should
pursue our objectives in a way that is compatible with these con-
cerns.
12 Brian Wilson
The issues
We need to look at the development of both trade policy and environ-
mental protection rules. We are currently working with our EU partners
to build support for a comprehensive approach to a new round of
trade negotiations. We are also actively pursuing the development of
key existing and future international conventions tackling global en-
vironmental problems such as climate change and ozone layer deple-
tion.
Protecting the environment and maintaining an open, and equitable
non-discriminatory multilateral trading system are both essential to the
achievement of our objective of sustainable development. There are
many effective internationally recognized measures which aim to
protect our environment. There is more to be done, although signifi-
cant progress has been made in the last 20 years or so with a number
of multilateral environmental agreements (MEAs). Liberalizing trade
helps to ensure that resources are used efficiently, it helps generate the
wealth necessary for development and environmental improvement,
and it encourages the spread of clean technology.
It is clear that these two systems – trade and environment – must ac-
commodate each other in order to be fully effective. It has been argued
that the WTO Agreements could frustrate the aims of some environ-
mental protection measures. Some have pointed to the report of the
WTO dispute settlement panel in the Shrimp/Turtle case as evidence of
this. But the Appellate Body has now reversed some of the panel’s
judgments.
Although the Appellate Body ruled against the US measure in that
case because of the application of the measure, it acknowledged that
the measure was legitimate in principle – a very significant decision.
The report certainly promoted the need to interpret WTO rules so that
they do not undermine environmental protection measures: ‘We have
not decided that the protection and preservation of the environment is
A strategic overview of the debate 13
1
United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, para. 185,
WT/DS58/AB/R (12 October 1998).
14 Brian Wilson
Labelling
On labelling, we know that consumer demands in this area are increas-
ing. We are, for example, committed to ensuring better labelling of
genetically modified foods. Consumers are looking for information on
the environmental effects of a product’s production and disposal. This
desire has led to greater use of suitable labelling by producers and re-
tailers. Voluntary initiatives of this kind in the marketplace should be
welcomed, especially if they open markets for sustainably produced
goods from developing countries.
Labelling schemes should be simple, non-discriminatory, transparent
and capable of independent verification. The process of verification
for such schemes should be achievable and affordable by smaller com-
panies and by those in the developing world. At the level of broad prin-
ciple, schemes that meet these criteria should be a useful complement
to a liberalizing trade policy.
Consumers should be able to purchase goods on a properly informed
basis. This is another area where the development of international stan-
dards can help establish the right degree of transparency both for gov-
ernment schemes and independent single-issue certification schemes.
There are clearly many more issues that we should address when
formulating policy, but there is simply no time to cover each one here.
16 Brian Wilson
Investment
So far, I have been talking mainly about the interaction between trade
liberalization and environmental protection. An equally important is-
sue for the future will be the relationship between environmental issues
and the liberalization of international investment.
The investment issue has been given a higher public profile by the
negotiation of the Multilateral Agreement on Investment, or MAI. It
now looks most unlikely that we will conclude the MAI in the near
2
United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, para. 159,
WT/DS58/AB/R (12 October 1998).
A strategic overview of the debate 17
future. But the issues that came up in the MAI context are still rel-
evant.
I am optimistic that these issues can be addressed in a way that every-
one can find satisfactory. In principle, there should be no conflict be-
tween the fair treatment of investors and the protection of the environ-
ment. Our aim is to make sure that these two goals are not allowed to
undermine each other in practice. The UK government – at least since
May 1997 – took a leading role in forcing this issue up the agenda in the
MAI negotiations and will continue to give it a high priority.
The priorities
So how should we be channelling our energies now? I think we should
concentrate on two areas.
First, we must recognize the value of international consensus on en-
vironmental protection. And we must continue to work to expand the
scope and the reach of the consensus. The United Kingdom will con-
tinue to play its full part in the development of key existing and future
international conventions tackling global environmental problems
such as climate change and ozone layer depletion. And we will work
to build consensus and develop mutual recognition of standards, and,
where desirable, to harmonize standards while ensuring that trade rules
are not used to impose unfair standards on developing countries.
Second, we must ensure that there is a better understanding between
the global trade and environment communities. It may be that a solu-
tion to some of our concerns will be found in a clarification of the inter-
face between the systems rather than in the alteration of established
principles. This will become apparent only with improved dialogue.
We need a continuing dialogue within government, between govern-
ment, business and civil society organizations, and on an intergovern-
mental level. For this dialogue to be fully effective, we will also have to
push for greater transparency in international organizations, and in
particular in the WTO, so that it can shed its image of a secret body and
deflect unwarranted criticisms about its deliberations.
Cooperation within and between governments will underpin the
compatibility of both sets of policies and their coherent development.
18 Brian Wilson
I think that the trade and environment frameworks are less in conflict
than some might claim. That does not mean that I dismiss the possibil-
ity of any conflicts. Governments themselves have a duty to balance
the objectives of both protecting the environment and upholding the
multilateral trading system, whether they are negotiating in a trade fo-
rum or an environment forum. It is therefore for parties to both existing
and new agreements to ensure individually and collectively that they
do not sign up to conflicting requirements.
Conclusion
Trade, investment and the environment are all increasingly global is-
sues. The international community has made great inroads into dealing
with these concerns at a global level. What we do not have is a frame-
work for how each of these systems overlap with or complement the
others. This is the area that we must explore and resolve. Solutions to
global problems will be found only through that consensus.
As a nation, we should not shy away from a leadership role and we
should be seeking opportunities for progress. But progress will come
only from an improved dialogue between all interested parties. We
cannot hide from the fact that environmental concerns can be used as a
smoke-screen for protectionist measures – with very immediate im-
pacts on people’s welfare in other parts of the world. So I want to see
A strategic overview of the debate 19
1
Examples include CITES, the Montreal Protocol and the Basel Convention.
2
The proposal to hold a High Level Meeting is reflected in the Quad Ministerial
Communiqué of 29–30 April 1998, the Report of the European Parliament adopted on 30
April 1998, various initiatives of the European Commission (e.g. the speech of Sir Leon
Brittan to the Bellerive Foundation on 23 March 1998), and, most recently, the call by
22 Gary P. Sampson
2
(cont)
President Clinton for a joint Ministerial Conference of Trade and Environment Ministers.
President Clinton asked that ‘a high-level meeting be convened, to bring together trade and
environmental ministers, to provide strong direction and new energy to the WTO’s
environmental efforts in the years to come, as has been suggested by the European
Commission’.
A strategic overview of the debate 23
of this meeting. Third, there is the preparatory stage for the WTO Min-
isterial Meeting taking place at the end of 1999 in the United States,
and the negotiations surrounding the formulation of the agenda for this
meeting. Fourth, there is the Ministerial Meeting itself and perhaps the
launching of a new round of negotiations.
Given the manner in which the WTO proceeds, it would seem reason-
able to divide the issues to be addressed, and the possible outcomes,
into categories, depending on the degree of government involvement
or negotiation in each case. Given the consensus-based nature of the
WTO, the need for members to take decisions requires collective deci-
sion-taking, probably intensive negotiation, and certainly not a rapid
outcome. On this basis, it is possible to envisage three sets of objectives
and outcomes. First, there are those that can be achieved if there is
enough informal support for the Director-General or the Secretariat to
undertake initiatives without formal discussion and decision-taking on
the part of the members. In such cases, consultation is important but
negotiation is not. Second, there are initiatives that require the collective
approval of members, but not necessarily changes in rules, rights or
obligations. Each WTO member has joined the organization because
the existing balance of rights and obligations is seen to be satisfactory.
Upsetting this balance may require negotiation in areas quite outside
those under discussion. There are, however, numerous examples where
members can operate expeditiously within the existing framework of
rules to achieve objectives that are considered important. Finally, there
are those objectives that can be achieved only through a change in
rules. The procedures for changing rules in the WTO are complex. In
practical terms, rule changes can be achieved only in comprehensive
rounds of trade negotiations where cross-sectoral trade-offs are possible.
The coming twelve months could be important for the trade and en-
vironment debate in the World Trade Organization. To take advantage
of the window of opportunity that exists at the present time, however,
will require careful consideration of the content of the proposals pre-
sented and the timing and nature of forthcoming important meetings.
David Wakeford
1
Editors’ note: The EC ‘Leghold Traps Regulation’ (Council Regulation 3254/91 of 4
November 1991) was concluded in 1991. It provided for imports of pelts of specified
species to be banned with effect from 1 January 1996 unless the Commission had
determined that the country from which they originated had taken adequate steps to prohibit
the use of the leghold trap, or that the trapping methods used for those species in that
country met internationally agreed humane trapping standards (which were the subject of
ongoing negotiations between the EU, Canada, Russia and the USA). In late 1995, Leon
Brittan decided to delay the introduction of the ban following complaints from the USA and
Canada that its introduction would be a breach of WTO rules.
28 Tom Burke
The two rule systems for global responsibility in the second half of
the twentieth century, the trade rule system and the environment rule
system, are among the most significant political accomplishments of
this period. And the development of both is an essential part of making
the transition to sustainable development. Without both sets of rules,
both commanding public confidence and both working efficiently,
there is no prospect of making a transition to sustainable develop-
ment. Therefore, the need to avoid collision between the two rule sys-
tems is the paramount policy and the political goal of this debate. It is
therefore alarming to look at the extent to which there are structural
factors that are promoting that collision. In other words, it is not a ques-
tion of people’s aspirations, the strengths or weaknesses of individuals
(or indeed of individual institutions), but, much more, the depth to
which some of the structural factors are embedded.
There is the prospect of the World Trade Organization adding 30
new members and having rigorously to insist, as it tries to absorb these
30 new members (including China, which is the biggest and most im-
portant of all), on maintaining its standards in the perfectly natural fear
that they may be dissolved in the extension of the club. There is a very
strong sense, particularly now, that economic turbulence will act as an
excuse for relaxing some of the disciplines of the trade system. There
is fear of an increased backsliding on these hard established rules, the
sort of fear that led a former assistant trade secretary in the United
States, writing in the International Herald Tribune, to talk about the
‘protectionist juggernaut’ that he saw developing.
At the same time as that structural dynamic is working, insisting on a
more rigorous application of trade policy, environmental degradation
is occurring at a very strong and accelerating pace. People look around
and they see the deterioration in environmental quality, whether at lo-
cal, regional or global level, increasing ever more quickly. At the same
time, there are powerful policy messages coming from a number of
quarters that, in order to deal with these issues in an economically effi-
cient way, the policy response must be pushed further and further up
the production chain, so that we are designing out solutions rather than
fixing them at the end. That whole agenda – eco-efficiency, life cycle
assessment, eco-labelling, environmental management systems and
30 Tom Burke
Sinking several billion dollars into a hole in the ground that cannot
be moved and being able to push a button and get half a billion dollars’
worth of capital out of the country in literally a split second create very
different views of how you want the world to be. The former gives a
much greater interest in stability, be it global or local stability, and a
much greater interest in a rounded perspective of what constitutes de-
velopment. Such companies operate inside a single information space
where, increasingly, the standards to which they have to operate on the
environment are global standards – and are also the standards that op-
erate in their home country.
For Shell, Rio Tinto, BP or any of the major companies, there is very
little choice but to operate to the same standards abroad as those at
home, because if they do not somebody will point out the difference
and they will find themselves in deep reputational trouble. Therefore, to
a very considerable extent, this makes that sort of company very differ-
ent from the procurers and the capital merchants. It makes them a very
powerful mechanism for the transfer of standards, because it is ex-
tremely important for them to ensure that the standards to which they
operate abroad are in some very real way compatible with the standards
to which they operate at home, not just for competitive reasons but also
so that they can make sure that their assurance chain works and that their
suppliers and contractors are operating in ways that they can live with.
It is that sort of company in particular that has an overwhelming in-
terest in ensuring that there is not some inadvertent collision between
the two rule systems, environment and trade. Therefore, to put the
point more positively, we need to work hard to achieve some sort of
successful merging of the rule systems, and we need to do that sooner
rather than later. Therefore it is important to have a grasp of what the
differences are, both in the theory and the culture. And the differences
are far more important than the similarities.
4
Editors’ note: A key problem faced by the Basel Convention is that the definition of
‘hazardous waste’– the object of its regulation – is contested. The Basel Convention
includes as wastes hazardous materials that are intended for recycling, whereas the recycling
industry often regards those same materials as ‘products’ or ‘secondary raw materials’ and
argues that they should not be subject to ‘waste’ regulation. See Jonathan Krueger,
International Trade and the Basel Convention (RIIA/Earthscan, 1999), pp. 99 et seq.
A strategic overview of the debate 33
are obeyed globally only to the extent to which countries agree to obey
them, and there is nothing anyone can do if someone does not want to
obey them. This is why, when most countries fail to achieve their frame-
work climate convention target – and most of the industrialized coun-
tries will do that some time around the year 2000 – nobody will say or
do anything, because there won’t be anything that can be said or done.
The trade rules are frequently opposed by the public – all sorts of
different publics with all sorts of different interests – but, by and large,
the environment rules are supported by the public.
These are important differences in culture. They are particularly im-
portant differences as we look at the prospects for merging the two sets
of rules. This is not just a question of merging two sets of language on
two pieces of paper: it is about merging two different cultures, different
institutions, trying to bring together two different political contexts. It
is a very complex and elaborate task and one of which the full scale
needs to be understood if there is to be any prospect of success.
for some of this policy resolution to take place outside of the negotia-
tions.
The key aspect of the OECD model is that people accept that they are
not negotiating: they are simply analysing and sharing their analysis.
That has often provided a very sound basis of future policy develop-
ment through negotiation. I do not see how a resolution of the con-
flicts, real and potential, between trade and environment rules can be
accomplished without some sort of forum like that to take on that task.
However, the WTO will not be halted in its tracks while this task is be-
ing carried out, and therefore, in some very real sense, many of these
issues will continue to be resolved through case law.
If we do not create the sort of forum we are talking about, and if we
leave it to case law alone, we will simply be overwhelmed by events,
and not in a way that any of us would like very much. As Winston
Churchill once remarked, ‘if something be not done, it will do itself
and in a manner pleasing to no one’.
If we are going to do things by case law, the one area where we
could make significant progress relatively rapidly is in enhancing
public confidence in the disputes process. The WTO disputes process
currently commands no public confidence, and the only reason why it
is not a source of greater outrage than it now is in some communities is
simply because most people do not have any idea of what it is doing.
The confines of the existing debate will not be adequate.
First, we need to create a transparent disputes process in which all of
the steps are open and visible, quickly and rapidly, so that people can
see not just the outcome but also the process and how the process is
working. Second, we need to create access to that disputes system by
right, not by permission. It should not be considered progress when
you are allowed to submit amicus briefs. It should by right be the case
that those people who have an interest in the outcome of a trade dis-
pute should be able to submit whatever they think in the way of input
to the process of a dispute. Third, the selection of dispute and appellate
panels needs to be very much more open and clear, and people need to
know who is taking these decisions on their behalf, how they came to
be selected, what their qualifications for selection were and what their
background, antecedence and interests are. We are not dealing with
A strategic overview of the debate 35
your money. Of course you do if you spend it; but what they really
mean is that you would get so much more for your money, and you
will get even more if you don’t spend the money! That is the difficulty
with that argument, so it is one that we have to watch very carefully,
because it is a very powerful argument.
One has to say very clearly that here is an area where governments,
politicians, are clearly going to act, where most of us think they ought to
act, but where they know perfectly well that they cannot act in the long
run unless there is some kind of global agreement. Although we can get
people to do it now – and I can usually shame an audience into accepting
that it is our fault so we have to do our bit first – there comes the moment
at which that argument ceases to have quite the impetus. It started in
America, and we will have to get over that in some way; and somewhere
in the early years of the next century we will find it quite impossible to
continue unless there is a clear connection between what we are doing
and what the developing countries, as they grow, are doing.
Of course, if there is to be such a connection it has to be one that in-
volves justice. There is no point in discussing this issue with develop-
ing countries unless you are prepared to accept that, if there is a global
problem that involves reducing emissions globally, then that reduction
cannot be on the basis of historical use: it has to be on some kind of
basis that has some connection with justice.
Historical use of course has to come into it. You cannot ask people to
change from having four per cent of the world’s population and 25 per
cent of the world’s emissions to having four per cent of the world’s
emissions overnight. Not only would it not be possible for them politi-
cally, but it would be extremely bad for the world economy. However,
at some point along this trajectory there is a hugely important element
of justice, which has to be seen not just by the poorer countries but also
by the richer countries. It is only by understanding what interdepen-
dence really means that they can begin to evolve a system that prop-
erly represents a global solution to a global problem.
40 John Gummer
This is the difficulty for those who put the argument forward that
somehow or other you must not stop the engine of world trade, and that
therefore there is a kind of inherent fairness about it because everybody
benefits. Of course it will not stand up; but it is very deeply ingrained. If
we want to talk about fairness, we have to do so in circumstances where
people understand that it does not matter what they think about it: it is the
practical price you pay for what you need. In other words, we should
stop talking about fairness in the sense of it being a moral responsibil-
ity – although I happen to hold that this is so – indeed, to stop talking
about it even as a religious responsibility (although I happen to hold that
too). What we have to say is that it is just a practical necessity. It doesn’t
matter what your argument is about it: either you find a way that is seen
to be fair enough for others to join in, or others won’t join in.
This is no longer a matter of theology or ideology, it is now a matter
of practical necessity. So if you want to solve this environmental prob-
lem and, I suspect increasingly, others – for example the environmen-
tal problems related to the oceans – then it can only be done if you cre-
ate a context of fairness. I define ‘fairness’ simply by the matter of
saying that it is a context which those who sign up to it think is fair, or
better still fair enough. That is, after all, the basis of most international
agreements. It is not that you actually agree with it, but that it is the best
you can get and it is reasonable enough for you to sell. That is the sort
of situation in which we have to work.
Now let us bring that back to the context of the WTO. In the WTO we
have a tough, effective, almost universally accepted system. It is one
that people take seriously, and yet one that has none of the restrictions,
none of the value judgments, that we have in our own countries. We
are faced with environmental problems which, if we are to solve, will
demand answers that will not be strictly amenable to the sort of mea-
surements the WTO has used up to now. These two things run abso-
lutely counter to each other. It is not just a matter of making sure that
the WTO is more environmentally friendly and thinks a bit more about
this, that and the other, and does not actually fall out with the Conven-
tion on International Trade in Endangered Species; it is something
much more fundamental than that.
42 John Gummer
the free market, as I am, I do not believe it is the most important thing
in life.
I very rarely make a party-political comment, and this is not a party-politi-
cal comment but just a quote from Quintin Hogg which I use because it is a
parallel. In defining Conservatives, he said that ‘Conservatives never think
that politics is the most important thing in life. Intelligent Conservatives think
that religion is more important; rather less intelligent Conservatives think that
hunting is more important’, and he said ‘Some Conservatives think that both
are more important’.
It is a good parallel with what we are talking about. What Hogg is
saying is that people who are committed to a certain political party,
who think it is an important thing, who work for it, spend a lot of their
time on it, still do not think it is the most important thing in life. That
seems to me to be the way we ought to look at trade. I think that trade
is very important. Free trade is vital. It is the only thing that will change
the future for people. The only way in which we will get the sort of
raising of standards of living in areas that so desperately need it is via
the trading mechanism. But I do not think it is the most important thing
in life. I certainly don’t think it is the only thing in life.
In a sense, what we are battling with here is a curious absolutism in
world decision-making, which is entirely absent in national decision-
making. I come at the end to where I started. If we are going to discuss
trade, investment and the environment, we need to do so bearing in
mind our own experience of how we have dealt with trade, investment
and the environment in our own countries. We have dealt with them in
a non-absolutist sense. We have said you have to make them work and
mesh together; that you cannot ignore any one of them; that you must
have environmental protection; that if you are going to have invest-
ment there must be protection for the investor, but there must also be
protection for those whom his investment affects.
When you deal with trade, you accept that you want a business-
friendly society. We now have no disagreement with that at all. Every-
body thinks it is good to have a business-friendly society, but every-
body also thinks that a business-friendly society does not mean that
you have a free-for-all, a system that is uninterested in the ability of all
members of that society to pay for the basics of life.
44 John Gummer
Introduction
It is perhaps worth starting with the underlying question: What is the
relevance of trade, investment and environment policy linkages for
developing countries? Trade and investment lead to growth, which in
turn creates the resources for poorer countries to tackle the problems
they face including those of an environmental nature. The linkages
between trade, investment, environment and development can, how-
ever, be more complex. Certain patterns of growth and development
can themselves cause environmental degradation, particularly in the
case of countries whose environmental policies are weak or unen-
forced. Also, there is no guarantee that resources provided by trade
will be used on environmental improvements, though the evidence
suggests that, as a country’s income rises beyond a certain level, the
negative effects of growth tend to lessen.
Moreover, developing countries themselves are concerned that envi-
ronmental policies may restrict their market access, or could be used as
a protectionist tool. More progress clearly needs to be made at the
multilateral level to reconcile different interests.
Addressing the concerns of developing countries on these issues
is therefore an important part of the resolution of conflict at the inter-
national level on trade, investment and environment. And the UK is
committed to ensuring that developing countries are fully integrated
into the multilateral trading system. The timing is critical. We need to
be prepared to negotiate about the concerns of developing countries
in the Millennium Round, where the environment will be one of the
important issues on the agenda. Unlocking the debate on trade and
environment will help make progress on a range of other trade issues.
This paper outlines broadly the range of activities that the UK De-
partment for International Development (DFID) has initiated to take
50 David Batt
this work forward, particularly those activities that stem from the re-
cent White Paper on International Development.1
1
Eliminating World Poverty: A Challenge for the 21st Century, DFID, November 1997.
Poverty and sustainability 51
• The UK is the fifth largest contributor (over £215 million) to the Glo-
bal Environment Facility, which is the major multilateral channel for
assisting developing countries meet their obligations under MEAs.
• DFID spent over £23 million on biodiversity projects in 1996–7.
• On climate change DFID is funding work on climate-friendly tech-
nologies and policies through its Energy Efficiency programme.
• DFID has committed £69 million to the Montreal Protocol’s Multi-
lateral Fund which meets the cost to developing countries of phas-
ing out ozone depleting substances.
Win–win approaches
Finally, there is a fourth area which was not drawn out explicitly in
last year’s development White Paper. This is the ‘win–win’ approach.
In brief, this means identifying areas where the removal of trade re-
strictions and distortions has the potential to yield both direct eco-
nomic benefits for developing countries and positive environmental
results.
54 David Batt
example, the United States and New Zealand have identified fisheries
as a sector where subsidies have led to over-capacity in developed
countries’ fishing fleets and depletion in certain varieties of world fish
stocks. The argument runs that the reduction or removal of these subsi-
dies would provide both a developmental ‘win’ (because it would pro-
vide increased market opportunities for developing-country exporters,
who would no longer need to compete on a playing field tilted against
them through subsidies to the fishing fleets of developed countries)
and an environmental ‘win’ (because it would slow down depletion of
stocks).
Fourth, in order to develop this list of examples, we need to under-
take more research. Two points about this. First, I do not think this re-
search need involve going out and collecting extensive primary data.
Our assessment is that a lot of the basic data needed are already avail-
able, for instance in UNCTAD and elsewhere, but that what has not yet
been done is to use the data to try to answer the sort of questions I have
been touching on. Second, this is the sort of work that DFID is now
supporting. This is not research for the sake of research: it is research
specifically linked to policy challenges. It is the sort of policy-based
research that DFID wants to undertake more and more of, in partner-
ship with others, not just on this crucial part of any forthcoming multi-
lateral round, but on others too.
Finally, important as this research is, I do not think that the questions
are capable of being answered fully by a process of analysis on its
own – by my asking someone, or a group of people, no matter how
expert, to go off into a room on their own with a pile of papers and a
pot of hot coffee. We need the ideas, the intuition, the experience, of a
larger group of people.
Building sustainable markets
Nick Robins
The challenge
It is now clear that achieving sustainable patterns of production and
consumption will involve long-term structural change in the world
economy. In the post-industrial economies of the OECD, improve-
ments in environmental performance of a factor of ten could be re-
quired over the next half century. Increasing global interdependence
means that this transformation will inevitably have trade implications.
The issue facing the world trade system is to work out how it can con-
tribute to this transition, and thereby generate sustainable flows of
trade.
In essence, sustainable trade is deceptively simple.1 Sustainable
trade takes place when the international exchange of goods and ser-
vices meets the four core criteria of sustainable development:
Making sustainable trade the norm is a different matter and will require
a long-term transformation of global markets, involving fundamental
changes in the policy and institutional architecture, in corporate prac-
tices and patterns of consumption. For developing countries, the chal-
lenge of sustainable trade is to ensure that they realize positive benefits
from this shift in terms of strengthened trade performance, improved
1
The International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED) has launched a
three-year project, ‘Stimulating Sustainable Trade’, aimed at providing practical guidance on
the mechanics of encouraging trade in sustainable goods and services, from the developing
world to the European Union.
Building sustainable markets 57
2
See R. Kumar et al., Responding to Global Standards: Case Study of the Textile Industry
in India, Indonesia and Zimbabwe, UNIDO, Vienna, 1998.
Building sustainable markets 59
Tourism The tourism sector is now the world’s largest industry, and
social and environmental concerns are of increasing importance in de-
ciding the choice of destination. As part of this there is a growing eco-
3
The Eco-Tex label is an independent labelling system that tests textile products for the
presence of harmful chemicals.
60 Nick Robins
Innovative producers Last, but not least, sustainable trade is also be-
ing driven by innovative producers in developing countries who see
opportunities for community and commercial development from tap-
ping these emerging export markets – some of whom are profiled in
the next section.
64 Nick Robins
4
Nick Robins and Sarah Roberts, Unlocking Trade Opportunities, IIED, London, 1997.
Building sustainable markets 65
making the transition. Yet, the small-scale sector that makes up the
bulk of India’s textile industry often lacks the skills, information and
resources to make the transition cost-effectively.
Costs and benefits Where special fair trade conditions have been es-
tablished, or where demand outstrips supply, producers can gain a
price premium. But this can be temporary phenomenon and can dis-
solve, as has already been the case for certified timber products. As a
result, social and environmental criteria simply become a basic re-
quirement for doing business, with producers facing the full costs of
investment and certification without offsetting price or market share
advantages.
Scale All these problems weigh most heavily on small and medium-
sized firms, which often lack the skills, information or resources to
5
See Konrad von Moltke et al., Global Product Chains, UNEP, Geneva, 1998, for a
detailed analysis of market power in commodity chains.
Building sustainable markets 71
Introduction
I am employed by Ghana’s Timber Export Development Board and I
am based in London. The Timber Export Development Board has the
task of promoting Ghana’s tropical wood and wood products in inter-
national markets. It is a government organization responsible to the
Ministry of Lands and Forestry, and is financed by levies on industry.
This paper outlines the trade and environment problems of the tropical
timber sector, focusing on the issues as they affect Ghana.
For some years there has been a selective environmental focus on
loss of tropical forest arising from the impacts of human activity. In
some countries there has been aggressive campaigning against the use
of tropical wood with an impact on market access and market success.
I aim to address these specific issues and to try to draw some conclu-
sions with wider relevance to the debate on the relationship between
trade, environment and investment.
Ghana’s forests
Geographically, Ghana extends to the north into drier savannah and
semi-desert which accounts for two-thirds of the land area, but the
south includes the wetter regions. The tropical forest covers about 7
per cent of the land area, and a large proportion of it is in the form of
legally constituted forest reserves.
Ghana is not a rich country. Its 14 million inhabitants include a large
number of low-income earners and land-reliant families. The country’s
export trade depends on a handful of products, gold, cocoa and timber
being the principal components. All three of these have environmental
1
This contribution is made in a personal capacity.
74 Moses Adigbli
impacts on the forest. Ghanaians also look to the forest for other goods
and services, using huge amounts of wood for fuel and charcoal, and
relying on the forest to supply meat and other non-timber products.
There was a time, as in Britain three hundred years ago, when the
productivity and existence of the forest could be taken for granted.
This is no longer the case. Britain has used up most of its own forests
and now relies on imports to supply more than 80 per cent of its wood
and wood fibre needs. Ghana is not yet in that position, but we are
aware that there are finite limits to our forests. The ever increasing de-
mands on it have to be regulated and supplemented if we are to have a
permanent forest resource capable of enabling a sustainable flow of
products to meet the needs of our own people and have a surplus for
export. There is now a widespread realization that urgent and strong
measures are needed to ensure the continuation of material, environ-
mental, cultural and communal benefits.
Our forest lands are owned by communities, and although signifi-
cant areas have legally and democratically been put under the care of
the government as forest reserves, outside these areas the forest is still
subject to the old ways. Rights of access and utilization are embedded
in the traditional and sometimes complex rights exercised through chiefs
and elders and recognized by government. Environmental groups are
often fiercely supportive of the rights of local communities, and such
rights are strongly in evidence in Ghana. But one cannot presume that
this automatically protects the forest. The rights for timber extraction
are matters of exclusive concessions or contracts involving the private
sector, government and community. These three sectors of society all
have to be involved in, and support, the ways in which forests are used
if there is to be successful commitment to sustainability. Each group
has rights and each group has responsibilities.
Discouragement of investment
This deliberate souring of the purchasing climate seems to be ignored
by governments of importing countries discussing world trade in inter-
national forums. On the one hand, international agencies and sources
of bilateral aid are actually encouraging better forest management, but
on the other they are doing nothing to keep markets open. Govern-
ments of importing countries are seldom inclined even to give guid-
ance to their own departments or to subnational governments on the
unacceptability of discrimination.
The situation may be affecting the development of Ghana’s forest
products industry in other ways. International institutions continue to
provide valued help, but an injection of capital and skills from invest-
ment sources in Britain are markedly absent. Historically there have
been political reasons for this, but today one suspects that investors are
frightened that their reputations would immediately come under fire
from the environmental extremists. One suspects that this discourage-
ment applies particularly to investors who have a keen sense of respon-
sibility towards the environment.
My colleagues and I are well aware that there are many different
kinds of environmentally concerned groups and that many do under-
‘Green consumerism’ and trade 79
stand the problems and try to help, but the extreme groups do us dam-
age and we resent it. Discouragement of potential investors deprives
us of capital, management and production skills and market linkages.
This is a negative aspect of the relationship between environmental-
ism and investment.
human race reacts with the world’s lands, seas and air, but we are less
able to indulge them because we don’t have the money.
2
The FSC is an international non-governmental body that is involved in the certification of
forests and the labelling of forest products according to principles, standards and criteria
laid down by its governing council.
‘Green consumerism’ and trade 81
3
The International Tropical Timber Organization (ITTO) has set the year 2000 as the date
by which timber from all tropical forests will be judged as being sustainably harvested. This
means that by that date each member country’s forest operations are expected to meet the
requirements of principles, criteria and management standards that were approved in 1995.
‘Green consumerism’ and labelling:
a retailer’s perspective
David Wheeler1
Introduction
These comments are based on The Body Shop’s experience of retail
trading in 47 countries around the world and extensive experience of
both voluntary and certified approaches to the provision of consumer
information. There are few elements of the green consumer agenda
with which The Body Shop has not been involved on an international
scale over the years, whether environmental, social (including fair
trade) or animal welfare-related.
The Body Shop believes that the scope for voluntary environmental
labelling to promote significant environmental benefits is limited. We
have experience of numerous international and national schemes oper-
ating in the consumer field. There is not a single scheme in any country
on the planet that we could say has made a significant impact in the
cosmetics and toiletries marketplace from the perspective of consumer
behaviour. The more general conclusion that we would draw is that,
with a few honourable exceptions, voluntary labels are at best much
ado about nothing, at worst a misleading and potentially highly con-
fusing market intervention.
There have been some successes, for example in organic labelling,
where there is a very active producer movement and a direct link to
consumer human health and well-being; another is the Forest Steward-
ship Council (FSC), where the issue is quite specific and significant
effort has been devoted to consensus-building across producer, NGO
and retail sectors. However, recent experience with the EU eco-labelling
1
Editors’ note: This is an edited version of David Wheeler’s evidence to the House of
Commons Environment Select Committee Inquity into the Environmental Impact of
Consumer Products. See Reducing the Environmental Impact of Consumer Products,
House of Commons Environment Select Committee 11 Report, HC 149, Vol. II, July 1999.
84 David Wheeler
2
Council Regulation (EEC) No. 880/92 of 23 March 1992 on a Community eco-label
award scheme, OJ L 099 11.04.92, p. 1.
‘Green consumerism’ and labelling 85
A way forward
If we were starting from first principles, The Body Shop would advo-
cate completely downgrading the public policy importance of volun-
tary, generic labelling initiatives. They will always exist, and certainly
will need to be made more transparent and honest through codes of
practice or regulatory intervention. But with the planet facing such ur-
gent social and environmental challenges, such initiatives should not
be allowed to distract us from more serious opportunities for progress.
Hence the Body Shop believes that the British government, in concert
with its global trading partners, should:
3
Council Regulation (EEC) No. 1836/93 of 29 June 1993, allowing voluntary participation
by companies in the industrial sector in a Community eco-management and audit scheme,
OJ L 168 10.07.93, p. 1.
86 David Wheeler
Conclusion
The approach advocated here is unashamedly pragmatic, but I believe it
would generate significant market signals and would help cut through
the current confusion in the market-place. It would accelerate environ-
mental and social change and would be consistent with wider objec-
tives on sustainability and poverty alleviation in developing countries.
This sort of approach does not remove the opportunity for consumer
action; it merely shifts the main motive force in the market-place to stan-
dards for government procurement. And, being pragmatic and ‘single
issue’ based, it would not attempt to resolve every social/environmen-
tal and ethical issue within a relatively weak, consumer market-based
framework, or indeed via voluntary and generic labels which create
little real motivation either for producers or consumers.
Good initiatives like FSC and organic certification would fit well
within such a scheme. There is absolutely no reason why government
purchasing standards should not prioritize sustainable forestry and
healthy food. Moreover, the approach could be readily applied to so-
cial and ethical criteria as well. Why should not certified ‘child-labour-
free’ be the main social criterion for government textile purchasing?
Part III
Resolving key WTO issues
Overview
A lawyer’s view
Damien Geradin
Introduction
The objective of this paper is to provide a short overview of the various
issues created by the interface between trade, investment and environ-
mental regulation. Most of the paper will concentrate on the links be-
tween trade and environmental protection, though investment aspects
will also be dealt with when relevant. Because of its introductory char-
acter, this paper will inevitably contain a number of simplifications.
More sophisticated analysis may, however, be found in my recent pub-
lications.1
As a starting point, it is essential to observe that the various inter-
linkages between trade, investment and environmental protection can
be properly identified only by making a number of basic distinctions.
Indeed, the impact of environmental regulations on trade and invest-
ment – and, conversely, the impact of trade and investment on environ-
mental regulations – may vary depending on the type of environmental
measure concerned.
A first distinction should be drawn between environmental measures
depending on whether they have been adopted unilaterally or pursuant
to multilateral environmental agreements (hereafter, MEAs). Each
category is considered in turn.
1
See, in particular, D. Geradin, ‘Trade and Environmental Protection in the Context of
World Trade Rules’, European Foreign Affairs Review, Vol. 2, Spring 1997, p. 33; D. Esty
and D. Geradin, ‘Market Access, Competitiveness and Harmonization: Environmental
Protection in Regional Trade Agreements’, Harvard Environmental Law Review, Vol. 21,
1997, p. 265.
92 Damien Geradin
Unilateral measures
A further distinction should be made here between three categories of
environmental measures: direct restrictions on trade; product stan-
dards; and process standards.2
2
For a discussion of these different categories of environmental measures see D. Geradin,
Trade and Environment: A Comparative Analysis of EC and US Law, Cambridge
University Press, 1997.
3
Generally on these exceptions see S. Charnovitz, ‘Explaining the Environmental
Exceptions in GATT Article XX’, Journal of World Trade, Vol. 25, 1991, p. 37.
Overview: a lawyer’s view 93
4
See US: Restrictions on the Imports of Tuna, 16 August 1991, reprinted in International
Legal Materials (‘Tuna/Dolphin I’), Vol. 30, 1991; and US: Restrictions on the Imports of
Tuna, 20 May 1994, reprinted in International Legal Materials, Vol. 33, 1994.
5
See US: Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, WT/DS58/AB/R
(12 October 1998).
6
See G. Shaffer, ‘The U.S. Shrimp Turtle Appellate Body Report: Setting Guidelines
toward Moderating the Trade-Environment Conflict’, Bridges Between Trade and
Sustainable Development, Vol. 2, No. 7, October 1998, p. 9.
7
Ibid.
94 Damien Geradin
Product standards
Product standards regulate the (environmental) characteristics of prod-
ucts. They include, for instance, packaging rules, sanitary require-
ments, vehicle exhaust emission standards, etc. Although such rules do
not impose direct restrictions on international trade, they may never-
theless have a trade restrictive effect on such trade in two categories of
circumstances.
First, product standards may be used as an instrument of protection-
ism when they discriminate on their face or in their effects against im-
ported products. This is, for instance, the case when a standard ex-
pressly imposes heavier requirements on imported products (formal
discrimination) or imposes similar obligations on domestic and im-
ported products, but in practice it has the effect of protecting the do-
mestic products to which it applies or other categories of domestic
products (material discrimination). As illustrated in the Reformulated
Gasoline dispute,8 such discriminatory standards are incompatible
with the national treatment principle contained in Article III. Unless
they can be justified under one of the exceptions contained in Article
XX, they will therefore be contrary to GATT.
Second, even when they do not discriminate on their face or in their
effects against imports, product standards may nevertheless have the
effect of making such imports more difficult. This may, for example,
be the case when countries require the use of certain types of labelling
or packaging. Such regulations impose an extra burden on manufac-
turers located in other countries since they will have to meet both the
standards of their own country and those of the country of sale, or per-
haps of several countries of sale. Despite the potentially restrictive ef-
fects on trade of such standards, they are not contrary to Article III of
GATT, whose national treatment principle only prevents discrimina-
tion.
8
See US: Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline, WT/DS2, (29 January
1996), where a dispute settlement panel found that a US EPA regulation treating imported
gasoline less favourably than domestic gasoline was not compatible with GATT Article III.
This panel decision was subsequently confirmed by the WTO Appellate Body, WT/DS/AB/
R, (29 April 1996).
Overview: a lawyer’s view 95
Process standards
Unlike product standards, process standards regulate not the character-
istics of products, but the production methods by which they are made.
As such, process standards do not restrict trade and there is nothing in
the GATT that prevents its members from regulating domestic produc-
ers that engage in polluting activities.
Difficulties may, however, arise when WTO Members attempt to use
trade measures in order to control the production processes used by
foreign producers. In order to achieve such control, Members can, for
instance, deny market access to products that have been produced pur-
suant to inadequate process standards, or impose a duty on such prod-
ucts (hereafter, ‘process-related trade restrictions’).
9
EC Measures Concerning Meat and Meat Products (Hormones), WT/DS26/AB/R, WT/
DS48/AB/R.
96 Damien Geradin
10
See J. Trachtmann, ‘Internationalization, Regulatory Competition, Externalization and
Jurisdiction’, Harvard Journal of International Law, Vol. 34, 1993, p. 47, 57.
11
See R. Carbaugh and D. Wassink, Environmental Standards and International
Competitiveness, World Competition,Vol. 16, p. 81.
12
See, e.g. ‘Gephart Bill to Allow Sanctions for Not Enforcing Environmental Laws’,
International Trade Reporter, Vol. 11, 30 March 1994, p. 500 (reporting Congressman
Gephart’s intention to propose legislation treating any failure to adopt proper environmental
standards as an unfair trade practice actionable under Section 301 of the Trade Act 1974).
13
D. Esty and D. Geradin, ‘Environmental Protection and International Competitiveness: A
Conceptual Framework’, Journal of World Trade, Vol. 32, 1998, p. 5.
Overview: a lawyer’s view 97
nomic studies we read tend to suggest that there is no specific link be-
tween the level of environmental regulation adopted by a country and
its economic performance in terms of the competitiveness of its indus-
tries on domestic and international markets, or its levels of investment.
Differences in environmental standards do not necessarily penalize
high-standard nations. Hence it seems to make little sense to adopt
trade measures such as bans or eco-duties in an attempt to equalize
production costs across jurisdictions.
A more difficult question is whether WTO Members should be al-
lowed to adopt trade measures to force low-standard nations to in-
crease their process standards in order to achieve specific environmen-
tal objectives. From a legal standpoint, process-related trade restrictions
violate GATT Articles I and III, and, for reasons discussed above, it is
unlikely that they are justifiable under Article XX. Moreover, from a
policy standpoint, there is general hostility among most WTO Mem-
bers for this type of restriction.
This hostility is motivated by two main objections. First, there is the
concern that one or several nations could use their superior commer-
cial power to impose their environmental standards on other nations
without their consent or participation in the development of such stan-
dards (the ‘eco-imperialism’ objection). Second, to use John Jackson’s
words, there is the concern that, ‘if a nation is allowed to use the pro-
cess characteristics as the basis for trade restrictive measures, then the
result would be to open large loopholes in the GATT’.14 The use of
environmental process characteristics as a basis for discrimination be-
tween products could trigger similar claims in other areas of social
policies, such as human and labour rights (the ‘slippery slope’ objec-
tion).
Thus, it appears that, from both law and policy standpoints, a multi-
lateral approach though which high-standard nations attempt to en-
courage low-standard nations to improve their environmental practices
by using incentive regimes will generally be more acceptable than any
form of unilateral restriction.
14
J. Jackson, ‘World Trade Rules and Environmental Policies: Congruence or Conflict?’,
Washington and Lee Law Review, Vol. 49, 1992, pp. 1127, 1243.
98 Damien Geradin
Multilateral measures
As we have seen, countries frequently resort to unilateral trade restric-
tions to advance environmental objectives. However, countries may
also adopt trade restrictions in order to implement trade provisions that
are contained in MEAs. Examples of MEAs containing trade provi-
sions are the Washington Convention on International Trade in Endan-
gered Species of Wild Flora and Fauna (CITES), the Montreal Protocol
on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer, and the Basel Convention
on the Control of Transboundary Movement of Hazardous Wastes and
their Disposal.
In agreements such as CITES and the Basel Convention, the ratio-
nale for trade restrictions between parties is clear. Trade must be re-
duced or eliminated because it represents the vehicle through which
the environmental damage occurs. Trade restrictions applying to non-
parties may be based on similar reasons. As illustrated by the Montreal
Protocol, such restrictions may also be designed to ensure that, by
staying out of the agreement, non-parties are unable to take a free ride,
i.e. to benefit from the environmental efforts brought about by the
agreement without bearing any of the costs it entails. On the contrary,
these trade provisions will generally place non-parties in a disadvanta-
geous position, thereby giving them an incentive to join.
Domestic measures adopted to implement these trade provisions
may, however, conflict with GATT in a number of ways. First, mea-
sures discriminating between parties and non-parties may violate
Article I’s most favoured nation (MFN) obligation; an example is the
adoption of an import or export ban on CFCs and CFC-containing
products and technologies against a WTO Member that is not a party
to the Montreal Protocol. Second, measures subjecting imported pro-
ducts to more stringent obligations than like domestic products may vio-
late the national treatment provision contained in Article III; an example
is the adoption by a party to the Basel Convention of a total ban on
foreign waste. Finally, import or export prohibitions, such as those
contained in CITES, may amount to quantitative restrictions contrary
to Article XI. In addition, the exceptions contained in GATT Articles
XX(b) or (g) may not be available to justify such restrictions. As in the
case of unilateral measures, a number of restrictions adopted pursuant
Overview: a lawyer’s view 99
Conclusions
The above discussion illustrates that the interface between trade, in-
vestment and environmental regulation raises a set of complex issues
100 Damien Geradin
15
See Esty and Geradin, supra n. 1.
16
See D. Geradin, ‘Free Trade and Environmental Protection in an Integrated Market: A
Survey of the Case-Law of the United States Supreme Court and the European Court of
Justice’, Journal of Transnational Law and Policy, Vol. 2, 1993, p. 141.
17
See generally, D. Esty, ‘Non-Governmental Organizations at the World Trade
Organization: Cooperation, Competition, or Exclusion’, Journal of International Economic
Law, Vol. 1, No 1, 1998, p. 123.
A view from the South
Magda Shahin
Introduction
Addressing the relationship between trade and environment has become
an integral part of any strategy for promoting exports of developing
and developed countries in order to enable them to compete in the
world market. To that end, countries are striving to understand better
this relationship with a view to pursuing their interests and advancing
their economies in a sustainable manner. It is noteworthy to recall here
how Rubens Ricupero, the Secretary General of UNCTAD, perceives
this complex and cumbersome relationship as a relationship between
two poles in a dialectical thesis, where the resulting synthesis should
conciliate the two ends. In contrast to many who would like to conceive
of the trade and the environment aspects as two sides of the same coin,
Ricupero stresses that linking trade to environment does not come as
something natural. It necessitates tremendous and enormous sacrifices
to reconcile these two ends. One should seek to integrate environment
into decision-making processes from the very beginning rather than
attempting to rectify a wrong-doing at the end by having recourse to
sanctions and trade embargoes. Technology, financing, market access,
knowledge and expertise are essential for the preservation and protec-
tion of the environment.
So far, such considerations have been given little attention in the
ongoing debate in the WTO. Some would argue that the WTO is nei-
ther a development forum nor a financing institution; others believe
that the debate has not yet been exhausted, and that some of these con-
siderations could find their way into future negotiations. If we today
would like to assess the prospects for the future of the trade–invest-
ment–environment debate, we cannot shy away from addressing this
complex relationship in its entirety. In fact, it is now beyond any doubt
that one of the prime reasons behind the collapse of the negotiations on
the MAI in the OECD was the failure to integrate environment consid-
Overview: a view from the South 103
erations into the negotiations from the outset. Any future negotiations
on trade/investment/the environment will have to answer first the ba-
sic question: are we ready to make recommendations on whether any
modifications of the provisions of the multilateral trading system are
required? Has the debate been exhausted? Are we prepared to set rules
and regulations?
Basic elements
Having said this, let me stress that the relationship between trade liber-
alization and environmental benefits is not a direct one. It is an indirect
relationship which passes through different production and consump-
tion patterns, levels of development, standards of living and the extent
of poverty in the society.
Let me also reiterate that the debate in the WTO to date has been set
within certain parameters and following a clear consensual mandate
which clarifies the extent to which such a debate is viable and legiti-
mate. In this context, I would like to base my assessment of how work
may continue on the trade–environment debate on three basic realities.
First, with regard to the Preamble of the ‘Marrakesh Agreement Es-
tablishing the World Trade Organization’,1 no one denies the impor-
tance assigned to the protection and preservation of the environment in
the Preamble. But it is equally true that the Preamble emphasized that
this be done ‘in a manner consistent with the countries’ needs and con-
cerns at different levels of economic development’. What is of signifi-
cance here is that the importance given to environment is not set in
absolute terms, but linked to the needs and concerns of the countries
and their levels of development. I could even argue further that priority
is attributed to development, as the protection and preservation of the
environment can be undertaken only to the extent consistent with the
level of development.
Second, the Marrakesh Ministerial Decision on Trade and Environ-
ment was clear in setting the terms of reference for WTO work on trade
1
The text of the Agreements can be found in WTO Secretariat, The Results of the Uruguay
Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations: Legal Texts, Geneva, 1995.
104 Magda Shahin
2
Report of the Committee on Trade and Environment, WT/CTE/W/40, 7 November 1996.
Overview: a view from the South 105
3
Article XX, entitled ‘General Exeptions’, gives ample opportunity to use measures to
protect (a) public morals and (b) human, animal or plant life or health, etc., provided that, as
the chapeau of the article stipulates, they are not applied in a manner that would constitute a
means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between countries where the same
conditions prevail, or a disguised restriction on international trade...
4
The TBT Agreement deals basically with technical regulations and international standards,
including packaging, marking and labelling requirements, and procedures for assessment of
conformity, and makes sure that they do not constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable
discrimination between countries where the same conditions prevail, or a disguised
restriction on international trade.
Overview: a view from the South 107
ment)5 are all cases in point, giving each WTO member the right to
set the level of protection that it deems appropriate for the environ-
ment, provided that it does not act against the basic principles of the
WTO as stipulated in Articles I and III of the GATT.6 If, however, a
state imposes stricter regulations on imported products than on those
domestically produced for environmental purposes, it is in violation
of GATT Article III. Once a substantive GATT requirement has been
violated, analysis shifts to Article XX, which incorporates a number
of General Exceptions, though this Article remains a cause of the
greatest uncertainty and continues to be a subject of controversial
interpretation.
5
The SPS Agreement, which forms an integral part of the Agreement on Agriculture,
reaffirms in its preamble that no Member should be prevented from adopting or enforcing
measures necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or health, subject to the
requirement that these measures are not applied in a manner that would constitute a means
of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between members where the same conditions
prevail, or a disguised restriction on international trade.
6
GATT Article I: Most Favoured Nation Treatment; GATT Article III: National Treatment.
108 Magda Shahin
It is worth noting that the Shrimp/Turtle case is the first conflict that
has arisen between the WTO and a MEA, in this case the Convention
on International Trade in Endangered Species (CITES). The report is
precedent-setting after the two Tuna/Dolphin reports, which were not
adopted because the United States blocked adoption. The Shrimp/
Turtle ruling is the first adopted WTO ruling concerning a trade em-
bargo based solely on domestic environmental legislation. The United
States is the only country that interprets Article XX so broadly as to
allow for extra-territorial measures to protect the environment beyond
its territories.
For the United States the case focused on the right of WTO members
to take measures under Article XX of GATT 1994 to conserve and pro-
tect natural resources, as reaffirmed and reinforced by the preamble to
the WTO Agreement. For the complainant, it was a case about the im-
position of unilateral trade measures designed to coerce other mem-
bers to adopt environmental policies that mirrored those in the United
States. The United States based its entire defence on Article XX, which
allows countries to take measures contrary to GATT obligations when
such measures are necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or
health. In this case the United States argued that the trade measure was
necessary because sea turtles were threatened with extinction and the
use of turtle excluder devices on shrimp nets was the only way to pro-
tect them effectively from drowning in shrimp nets. Overall, the panel
stressed the WTO’s preference for multilaterally negotiated solutions.7
Furthermore, the panel focused its analysis on the headnote or cha-
peau of Article XX, which requires legitimate trade restrictions to be
applied ‘in a manner which would not constitute a means of arbitrary
or unjustifiable discrimination between countries where the same con-
ditions prevail or a disguised restriction on international trade’. The
panel found that interpreting the chapeau in a way that would allow
importing countries to restrict market access according to exporters’
adoption of ‘certain policies, including conservation policies’ would
mean that ‘GATT 1994 and the WTO Agreement could no longer serve
7
United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, Report of
the Panel, WT/DS58/R, 15 May 1998, pp. 278–300.
Overview: a view from the South 109
8
Ibid.
110 Magda Shahin
9
United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, AB-1998-4,
WT/DS58/AB/R, 12 October 1998.
Overview: a view from the South 111
Eco-labelling
That the Singapore report failed to reach any agreed conclusions on
eco-labelling or any resolution of the ‘non product-related PPMs’ issue
was due to the fact that views remained wide apart during the whole
debate. The two issues continue to be difficult to resolve and necessi-
tate further work before final conclusions can be negotiated. The ques-
tion remains open: are we ready and willing to legitimize environmental
‘policies’ and ‘values’ in the WTO, which is a rule-setting body? How
can we translate environmental preferences into strict rules? Many con-
tinue to argue in favour of disciplining eco-labelling schemes on the ba-
sis of the concepts of ‘equivalence’ and ‘mutual recognition,’10 where
each country sets its standards according to its own values as stipulated
by Agenda 21. Aiming to harmonize or internationalize non-product-
related PPMs on the basis of any set of multilateral guidelines means
10
Editors’ note: ‘Mutual recognition’ could involve e.g. recognizing another country’s eco-
labelling scheme as equivalent to your own so that products awarded under one label would
automatically qualify under the other. The notion of ‘equivalence’ is closely related and
could mean e.g. that individual criteria under different schemes were recognized as
‘equivalent’, or that an individual product could meet different but ‘equivalent’ criteria to
those set by a particular scheme and still be recognized as falling within it.
114 Magda Shahin
11
UNCTAD Secretariat, ‘Effects of Environmental Policies, Standards and Regulations on
Market Access and Competitiveness, with Special Reference to Developing Countries,
Including with Least Developed Among Them, and in the Light of UNCTAD Empirical
Studies’, Environmental Policies,Trade and Competitiveness: Conceptual and Empirical
Issues, UNCTAD, TD/B/WG.6/6, 28 March 1995.
116 Magda Shahin
12
Ibid.
13
Ibid.
118 Magda Shahin
14
Ibid.
120 Magda Shahin
In the run-up to the Singapore Report, it was agreed in the light of the
width and depth of the existing gap between negotiators that further
analysis and examination was needed in the future before any con-
sensual decision could be taken. Developing countries had insisted
throughout the debate that there should be an explicit reference to ad-
dressing charges and taxes that relate only to product or product char-
acteristics that are covered by WTO provisions. Owing to resistance,
mainly from the United States and the European Community, refer-
ence was made to the need for WTO members to apply environmen-
tal charges and taxes in line with the ‘existing scope’ of WTO provi-
sions. The debate on this issue remains wide open to the results of
further study of the environmental effectiveness and potential trade ef-
fects of environmental taxes and charges, particularly their effects on
market access and competitiveness.
Conclusion
The future will carry with it an interesting and a multifaceted debate
on the interlinkages between trade, investment, the environment and
development. There is readiness as well as willingness on the part of
the majority of countries to enter into an open-ended negotiation, if
necessary, for applying WTO rules and regulations to promote envi-
ronmental protection, but also to discipline the use of trade mea-
sures for environmental purposes. The case, as we have seen, is far
from settled. Developmental concerns will have to be brought into the
debate through the front door and cannot be treated as a trickle-down
effect of investment or trade. How to ensure that developmental aspects
are part and parcel of the overall consideration of this complex rela-
tionship must not be overlooked. This should be carefully considered
Overview: a view from the South 121
An overview
Duncan Brack
Introduction
The aim of this paper is to explore the interrelationship between multi-
lateral environmental agreements (MEAs) and the multilateral trading
system (MTS), the complex of trade agreements centred around the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and overseen by the
World Trade Organization (WTO). The paper provides an outline pro-
posal for a way forward in the context of the forthcoming High Level
Meeting of trade and environment ministers and the subsequent Mil-
lennium Round of trade negotiations.
The paper starts from the assumption that the removal of barriers to
international trade, and the protection of the global environment, are
both desirable objectives. It is further assumed that in certain cases
these two objectives do, or are likely to, come into conflict, and that it
is desirable to derive a way to reach the optimal balance of trade liber-
alization and environmental protection in these instances.
Nearly 200 MEAs currently exist, with memberships varying from a
relatively small group to about 170 countries – which means, effec-
tively, the whole world. Over 20 of these incorporate trade measures,
i.e. restraints on the trade in particular substances or products, either
between parties to the treaty and/or between parties and non-parties.
Although this is a relatively small number, it includes some of the most
important, such as the 1973 Convention on International Trade in En-
dangered Species (CITES), the 1987 Montreal Protocol on Substances
that Deplete the Ozone Layer and the 1989 Basel Convention on the
Control of Transboundary Movements of Hazardous Waste. A series of
MEAs recently signed or currently under negotiation, including the
1997 Kyoto Protocol on Climate Change, the Rotterdam Convention
MEAs: an overview 123
Subject to the requirement that such measures are not applied in a manner
which would constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination
between countries where the same conditions prevail, or a disguised restric-
tion on international trade, nothing in this Agreement shall be construed to
prevent the adoption or enforcement by any contracting party of measures:
… (b) necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or health …
… (g) relating to the conservation of exhaustible natural resources if such
measures are made effective in conjunction with restrictions on do-
mestic production or consumption.
1
United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, paras. 131–4
WT/DS58/AB/R, 12 October 1998.
2
Ibid., paras. 166–72.
3
Ibid., para. 161.
128 Duncan Brack
Trade measures employed under the three main MEAs cited above
are now unlikely to be challenged in the WTO because of the wide
international acceptability they enjoy – though this is perhaps less
true of the Basel Convention, where the amendment banning trade in
waste between OECD and non-OECD countries (not yet in force) has
aroused hostility among some of the industries involved. The possible
MTS incompatibility of the amendment has been raised explicitly by
those opposed to the principle as an argument against adopting or
ratifying it.
This ‘political chill’ argument is also relevant to other MEAs. At-
tempts to include trade provisions in the International Convention for
the Conservation of Atlantic Tuna, and in agreements to control driftnet
fishing, were shelved because of a fear that they would be inconsistent
with GATT rules. The same issue was raised in last year’s negotiations
over the Kyoto Protocol and in discussions this year over the Rotterdam
Convention on Prior Informed Consent.
The continuation of this potential conflict between the MTS and
MEAs is undesirable for a number of reasons including the following:
• the fact that is not known for certain how a dispute panel would
rule on an MEA trade measure creates an unstable and uncertain
situation. On the face of it, it does appear absurd that the operation
of an important element of international law should be subject to a
panel of three individuals deciding what they think ten lines of
printed text (the relevant sections of GATT Article XX) written fifty
years ago could mean in a vastly changed international environ-
ment;
• it creates the spectre of a potential challenge to an existing MEA,
bringing the two international regimes of trade liberalization and
environmental protection directly into conflict;
4
Ibid., para. 165.
MEAs: an overview 129
Court of Justice as the superior body. Proposals for a new World Envi-
ronmental Organization (for instance by Chancellor Kohl at the UN
General Assembly Special Session, ‘Earth Summit 2’, in June 1997)
have had at least partly in mind the objective of creating a balancing
institution to the WTO, though the interrelationship between such a
WEO and the WTO was not, and has not been, explored in any detail.
It is interesting to note that the 1948 Charter for the International Trade
Organization (ITO) (the intended third leg of the Bretton Woods tripod,
never in fact adopted because of US opposition) did provide that a
member prejudiced by an ITO decision could seek an advisory opin-
ion from the ICJ, whose opinion would then bind the ITO. If Thomas
Cottier’s analysis of the WTO as increasingly assuming ‘constitutional
functions in a globalising economy’ (WTO Symposium, 17–18 March
1998) is accurate, then this argument may need to be addressed sooner
rather than later.
The second option, determining that one legal system is superior to
the other, is de facto, even if not de jure, the position as it stands at
present. As noted above, the validity of trade measures in MEAs could
be challenged under the WTO, and a WTO dispute panel would then
rule on their compatibility with the MTS. Although panels have be-
come steadily more aware of and more open to environmental argu-
ments (the decision of the Appellate Body in the Shrimp/Turtle case to
accept ‘non-requested information from non-governmental sources’5
is a useful step forward), they are nevertheless composed of interna-
tional trade experts who reach decisions in accordance with a body of
international trade law – indeed, they cannot do otherwise, since this is
the function of the WTO. The MTS has been constructed by trade ne-
gotiators with relatively little awareness of environmental requirements
and policies, and, despite a number of references to environmental
objectives in some of the WTO agreements, it is not well attuned to
environmental imperatives even though it cannot avoid interacting
with policies for environmental protection.
Equally, of course, it could be argued that MEAs are constructed by
environmental negotiators with little awareness of trade law and the
5
Ibid, paras. 104–10.
MEAs: an overview 131
The use of waivers has been referred to as the ex post approach. Article
XXV of the GATT provides for the granting of a waiver from other
GATT obligations ‘in exceptional circumstances’; Article IX of the
WTO Agreement extends this to the MTS as a whole. Such waivers,
however, are usually time-limited, can be considered only on a case-
by-case basis, and require a three-quarters majority of WTO members
to vote for them. Once again, they reinforce the existing hierarchy,
firmly placing the WTO in judgment over MEAs; they cannot contrib-
ute to certainty about the relationship between MEAs and the MTS;
and they do not fulfil any of the criteria set out above.
In contrast, the so-called ex ante approach implies modification of
the MTS in some way. One possible method is a ‘listing’ of those par-
ticular MEAs whose provisions are deemed to be compatible with the
MTS. This is similar to the approach taken by the North American Free
Trade Agreement (NAFTA), which provides that, in the event of con-
flict between itself and CITES, the Montreal Protocol or the Basel Con-
vention (or other MEAs where all NAFTA parties agree), the provi-
sions of the MEA should take precedence over the MTS – though it
134 Duncan Brack
also adds that parties must use the means least inconsistent with the
NAFTA in implementing the MEAs. While more attractive than the
waiver approach, this nevertheless involves the WTO in reaching a
decision over which MEAs it considers acceptable and which it does
not; it still does not create any certainty over the relationship with
MEAs in general.
A broader solution is preferred, dealing with MEAs as a category
rather than one by one. This implies a ‘criteria-specific’ modification
of the MTS. The clearest political message would be to achieve this via
amendment of the GATT. The EU proposal in the CTE, for example,
was for a new sub-paragraph of Article XX, covering measures ‘taken
pursuant to specific provisions of an MEA complying with the “Un-
derstanding on the relationship between measures taken pursuant to
MEAs and the WTO rules”’.6 The proposed Understanding included
a simple definition of an MEA and stated that measures taken pursuant
to the specific provisions of the MEA should be presumed to be ‘nec-
essary’ for the achievement of its environmental objectives, though they
still remained subject to the requirements of the chapeau to Article XX.
This particular approach now looks a little dated; since the EU pro-
posal was put together, a number of WTO panels have found trade
measures in unilateral trade–environment cases to be justified under
either paragraphs (b) or (g) of Article XX, but then failed them under
the chapeau. (Earlier panels had failed them under (b) and (g), and
never reached the chapeau.) If it is accepted that MEA trade measures
would be likely to be treated similarly, then there is little point in add-
ing a new paragraph: what would be required is amendment of the
headnote itself. Since this would have implications for every category
of exceptions to the GATT, and for unilateral as well as multilateral
trade measures, it would be exceptionally difficult – to put it mildly –
to negotiate. Finally, the procedures for amendment of the GATT are
themselves quite stringent and time-consuming.
6
WTO CTE, Non-paper by the European Community, 19 February 1996.
MEAs: an overview 135
Conclusion
The Millennium Round offers an excellent opportunity for the resolu-
tion of the potential conflict between the MTS and MEAs with trade
MEAs: an overview 137
Overview
European industry considers that the relationship between trade mea-
sures contained in multilateral environmental agreements (MEAs)
and the WTO should be resolved at the 1999 WTO High Level Meet-
ing on trade and the environment. The WTO needs to make a clear
statement in support of multilateral solutions to global environmental
problems.
European industry considers that trade measures taken pursuant to
MEAs should be accommodated by the WTO. The accommodation of
these trade measures could be achieved by introducing into GATT Ar-
ticle XX(b) the words ‘and the environment’ and by adding to this
amendment an Understanding on the relationship between trade mea-
sures taken pursuant to MEAs and the WTO rules.
The Understanding needs to set out certain basic criteria that MEAs
have to meet in order to benefit from the WTO accommodation, in par-
ticular a test as to whether the trade measure is necessary to achieve the
environmental objective of the MEA. If the MEA meets the criteria, the
trade measures will be presumed to be necessary within the meaning of
GATT Article XX(b). A challenge remains possible, but the challenger
needs to rebut the presumption of necessity. Thus, European industry
favours an ex ante approach combined with the possibility of very lim-
ited ex post WTO review of the trade measure.
1
Editors’ note: This paper is an annotated and updated version of the UNICE Position
Paper, ‘UNICE Position on the Relationship between the Provisions of the Multilateral
Trading System and Trade Measures for Environmental Purposes, including those Pursuant
to Multilateral Environmental Agreements’, dated 22 July 1996.
MEAs: an industry perspective 143
Introduction
The key issue is whether the WTO should judge trade measures taken
pursuant to MEAs more leniently than trade measures taken unilater-
ally – in other words, whether GATT Article XX should be less rigor-
ously applied in trade disputes involving trade provisions taken pursuant
to an MEA than it is normally applied.
The main problem with trade measures allowed by MEAs is discrimi-
nation. Some MEAs allow trade measures to be taken against non-par-
ties. These measures are allegedly considered necessary to achieve the
environmental aims of the MEAs concerned. But one of the pillars of the
WTO, and its predecessor the GATT, is most favoured nation treatment
and the associated principle of non-discrimination. Trade measures
against non-parties to an MEA that are members of the WTO can be
accepted only if they meet the conditions of GATT Article XX.
MEAs and the WTO are international agreements which bind their
members. The WTO does not take priority over MEAs and MEAs do
not take priority over the WTO: the WTO and MEAs exist in parallel.
The WTO is the multilateral agreement dealing with trade issues and is
therefore, and rightly so, the ultimate forum for deciding on trade is-
sues. MEAs rule on international environmental issues. If a WTO
member attacks a trade measure taken by a party to an MEA, the WTO
dispute settlement system could rule that the measure was inconsistent
with WTO rules. Such a ruling could put into question the objectives of
the MEA and could subject the WTO to criticism in so far as the WTO
should not second-guess the decisions taken by the members of an
MEA. While for the time being no trade measure taken pursuant to an
MEA has been attacked in the WTO, the issue of the relationship be-
tween the WTO and MEAs needs to be resolved.
Should Article XX, therefore, be changed in order to accommodate
trade measures taken pursuant to MEAs? Industry’s short answer to
this question is a conditional ‘yes’.
European industry considers that the WTO is not the right body to
deal with environmental issues. Some environmental issues could,
however, become important in case of a WTO dispute, such as the
question of whether it is necessary to achieve the environmental aim of
the agreement or whether the trade measure is the least trade-restric-
144 Reinhard Quick
ops a set of criteria that MEAs containing trade measures have to re-
spect, coupled with a very limited ex post review of the trade measure
in question.
UNICE favours an amendment of GATT Article XX(b) together
with an Understanding on the relationship between trade measures
taken pursuant to MEAs and the WTO rules. The Understanding would
set out the basic criteria that the MEA has to meet and would spell out
that trade measures taken pursuant to an MEA meeting the criteria
would be presumed to be necessary within the meaning of GATT
Article XX(b).
In the Understanding, the WTO should elaborate on the following
criteria:
UNICE and other business organisations have repeatedly stated that the
issue of scientific evidence, the necessity test, the least-trade-restrictive test
are indispensable requirements which also have to be respected by the ne-
gotiators of an MEA.
The concept of necessity is viewed as fundamental in the interpretation of
GATT Article XX. GATT has been an agreement on trade which provided
for its Contracting Parties to take measures for non-trade purposes which
were inconsistent with the GATT obligations only if the measures were nec-
essary to achieve the stated non-trade objective. This approach is contin-
MEAs: an industry perspective 147
ued in the WTO and is reflected not only in Article XX but also in the WTO
Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT) and the Agreement on the
Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (SPS).
UNICE is concerned that the Commission’s proposal gives environmental
negotiators a carte blanche to deviate from the most fundamental principles
of the WTO. The scope of WTO review of trade measures taken pursuant to
an MEA cannot be limited in such a drastic way as proposed by the Com-
mission.
At stake is the issue of how the WTO should handle disputes brought by
non-signatories of the MEA against trade measures decided by the signato-
ries of an MEA, in other words, the issue of most-favoured-nation treatment
and the principle of non-discrimination. In such a situation, the fundamen-
tal WTO principles cannot be given up without strong evidence that the
measure is really necessary to protect the environment.
The Commission itself has stated in its Communication on Trade and Envi-
ronment that ‘the use of trade restrictions within MEAs should not go be-
yond what is necessary to ensure the effectiveness of such agreements and
the achievement of their environmental objectives’. UNICE is somewhat
puzzled that this statement has not been introduced by the Commission as
a prerequisite for the Understanding as well.
UNICE therefore suggests that trade measures taken pursuant to MEAs
should only be accommodated by WTO if the Understanding contains at
least the necessity criterion. The application of the Commission’s concept
without this safeguard would leave WTO members defenceless against
trade measures provided for in an MEA whose purpose is not guided by
environmental, but by socio-economic, political, or moral considerations.
It would be an open invitation for protectionism if signatories of an MEA
could take trade measures against non-signatories without having to justify
the necessity of the trade measure. Such a far-reaching deviation from tradi-
tional WTO principles has to be resisted.
The adoption of the report of the WTO Appellate Body in the Refor-
mulated Gasoline case brought both the industry’s and the European
Community’s positions closer together in respect of the necessity ar-
gument. The Community had suggested that trade measures contained
in MEAs should be checked only in relation to the chapeau of GATT
Article XX and not with respect to the other tests contained in Article
XX. However, at that time the chapeau had never been interpreted by
a panel.
148 Reinhard Quick
• Sound science The rationale for the MEA should be based on sound
science. This issue, as such, has no relation to trade. The necessity
of a trade measure can, however, be demonstrated only with scien-
tific evidence. The specific provisions of the WTO SPS and the TBT
Agreements can serve as a reference for MEA negotiators.
• Global participation The MEA should be global and should deal
with a global environmental problem. MEAs should be negotiated
in a transparent way. They should encourage participation by all
interested and potentially affected parties. Global participation
should be defined as participation by countries that account for a
substantial proportion of the activity giving rise to the agreement.
• Regional agreements Industry is reluctant to give trade measures
taken pursuant to regional environmental agreements the same
WTO accommodation as trade measures taken pursuant to a true
MEA. The reason for this position is simple: a minority of countries
MEAs: an industry perspective 149
Subject to the requirement that such measures are not applied in a manner
which would constitute a means of arbitrary and unjustifiable discrimina-
tion between countries where the same conditions prevail, or a disguised
restriction on international trade, nothing in this agreement shall be con-
strued to prevent the adoption or enforcement by any contracting party of
measures:
(b) necessary to protect human, animal, plant life or health or the environ-
ment…
The addition of the word ‘environment’ into Article XX(b) should not
cause any difficulties for WTO members. The WTO preamble refers to
the protection and preservation of the environment. It is therefore a
logical consequence to introduce into the exceptions contained in Ar-
150 Reinhard Quick
ticle XX the notion that the protection and preservation of the environ-
ment can be used to justify measures that would otherwise be inconsis-
tent with the WTO.
Addition of the word ‘environment’ is not sufficient to address the
relationship between WTO and MEAs. Therefore industry follows the
Commission’s concept of an Understanding on the relationship be-
tween trade measures taken pursuant to MEAs and the WTO rules.
The WTO’s accommodation of trade measures taken pursuant to an
MEA which meet the criteria of the Understanding would be effected
by means of a rebuttable presumption. These trade measures would be
presumed necessary in the meaning of Article XX(b). In other words, if
the prerequisites of the Understanding are met, the trade measure taken
pursuant to the MEA would be accorded the benefit of the doubt. A
WTO challenge would remain possible, but the challenger would have
to overcome a higher procedural threshold than if a unilateral measure
were being challenged. Given the notions of sustainable development
and the protection and preservation of the environment in the preamble
to the Agreement establishing the WTO, industry considers that a chal-
lenger of the trade measure would not be able to rebut the presumption
unless it could demonstrate that the negotiators of the MEA had not
met the criteria laid down in the Understanding.
Finally, there are some practical suggestions concerning the imple-
mentation of this approach:
of a certain trade measure with the WTO, the WTO should, upon
request of the negotiators of an MEA, ask a member of the WTO
Appellate Body to advise the MEA negotiators.
Process and Production Methods
Introduction
The impact of environmental standards on market access and the pos-
sibility that they could become non-tariff barriers to trade has been an
issue of special concern for developing countries. 1 At the same time,
there has been growing interest in new trading opportunities that may
arise for companies in both developed and developing countries that
are moving towards higher environmental performance in terms of
both products and production processes.
Traditionally attention has focused on product standards. More re-
cently, however, increased attention has been paid to standards relating
to process and production methods (known as PPMs).2 One reason is
1
This paper updates an earlier paper by René Vossenaar and Veena Jha, ‘Environmentally
Based Process and Production: Some Implications for Developing Countries’, in Veena Jha,
Grant Hewison and Maree Underhill (eds), Trade, Environment and Sustainable
Development: A South Asian Perspective, 1997. It also draws from UNCTAD, Integrating
Trade, Environment and Development, Recent Progress and Outstanding Issues, TD/B/
COM.1/3, December 1996.
2
This paper focuses on measures targeting non-product-related PPMs, which do not
address a product’s final characteristics, but are intended only to control environmental
effects caused during production. It excludes PPMs that are related to the product. When
PPMs are related to the product, the use of PPM standards may have practical advantages
over product standards. In certain cases it may be more efficient and more economic to
control the process rather than the product itself to ensure product quality. Sometimes it may
be technically difficult or even impossible to control product characteristics by inspecting
the product. For example, the ISO 9000 quality system uses the term ‘special processes’ to
describe processes that cannot be fully verified by subsequent testing of the product, and
where process deficiencies may become apparent only after the product is in use. An
example can be founded in plastic moulding; the ability of a moulded product to withstand
stress may depend on the uniformity of dispersion of additives, moulding temperature and
other factors in the production process.
PPMs: sizing up the issues from the South 153
that environmental problems are more often associated with the pro-
duction process, than with the product itself. PPM-related standards are
becoming more stringent and comprehensive, particularly in devel-
oped countries, in response to improved understanding of environ-
mental risk and public preference for tighter environmental protection.
The use of PPM-based standards, which is essential for environmen-
tal purposes, should in most cases not result in conflicts with trade
rules. To the extent that environmental externalities are limited to the
exporting country, with their effects not being transmitted through the
product to the environment of the importing country, there is little jus-
tification for applying PPM-based standards to imported products. Fur-
thermore, current international trade rules do not restrict the right of
countries to set PPM standards appropriate to their own environment
and development. The international community generally recognizes
that global environmental problems caused by PPMs should be ad-
dressed on the basis of multilateral cooperation, preferably through
multilateral environmental agreements (MEAs).
Some issues have nevertheless been put forward. One is the com-
petitiveness issue. Although rigorous process standards generally have
positive effects on sustainable development, by requiring the internal-
ization of external environmental costs and by removing inefficiency,
concerns about maintaining competitiveness dissuade a country from
applying rigorous PPM standards. Concerns here include friction over
‘hidden’ environmental subsidies, ‘eco-dumping’, and pressures for
harmonization of PPM-based standards which may be inappropriate
for developing countries. It would appear, however, that progress has
been made on these issues and that some early pressures for trade mea-
sures, which some perceived as being necessary to ‘level the competi-
tive playing field’, have now largely been set aside.
An issue of major concern, in particular to developing countries, is
that PPM-based standards may result in the unilateral use of extra-terri-
torial trade restrictions. This issue has been at the centre of the trade–
environment debate, ever since the GATT panel in the first Tuna/
Dolphin case. In general, WTO rules do not permit the application of
non-product-related PPMs to imported products. The question is then
the extent to which conditioning market access on exporting countries’
154 René Vossenaar
3
UNEP, with the cooperation of UNCTAD, is undertaking work in this area. Discussions
in the WWF Expert Panel on Trade and Sustainable Development (EPTSD) are also
relevant in this context.
PPMs: sizing up the issues from the South 155
4
There is no definition of ‘like products’ in the GATT, and the practice has been for dispute
panels to determine what constitutes a ‘like product’ on a case-by-case basis, taking into
account the objective and purposes of the chided regulation or measure. Dispute panels have
generally taken the view that, while tariff classification could be one of the criteria, the final
determination should not be made solely on this basis. Other criteria, such as the nature of
the product, its intended use, its commercial value, price and substitutability, should also be
taken into account when determining what is or is not a ‘like’ product. See Vinod Rege,
GATT Law and Environment Related Issues Affecting Trade of Developing Countries,
1994.
5
A slightly different problem may arise in the case of transgenics and genetically
engineered species. An interesting case in point, which emerged in India, is that of
Monsanto, which tried to register a patent for a gene code-named ‘terminator’. The special
156 René Vossenaar
5
(cont)
... property of this gene is that it mutates at the end of its life span. Cross-pollination with
plants using this gene could have serious deleterious effects on the environment. Thus,
India, on grounds of public health and the environment, rejected Monsanto’s application to
patent this gene.
PPMs: sizing up the issues from the South 157
gies’ may result in cost savings over the long term. In addition, some
sectors will actually benefit if large markets exist for their particular
‘environmental goods and services’.
Studies have shown that on average environmental costs amount to
only one to two per cent of total production costs. However, they have
a more significant impact on capital costs, particularly in pollution-
intensive industries. In addition, most of these studies have considered
only part of the environmental protection costs, such as specific indus-
trial pollution control costs.6 Moreover, these studies have not picked
up micro impacts; for instance, in particular sectors or firms, differ-
ences in process standards and regulations may have more serious cost
impacts if environmental externalities are more fully internalized.
In expanding sectors, differences in environmental standards between
countries should not raise problems for competitiveness. However, in
sectors that are intensive in natural resources, and are heavily depen-
dent on price as a factor of competitiveness, even small differences
in standards may have a significant impact. This applies especially to
low value added products, which constitute the bulk of the exports
from developing countries. The ability of developing countries to
implement higher environmental standards will also be limited by
financial and technological constraints, and they may find it difficult
to subsidize the development of environmentally sound production
methods.
6
One shortcoming of many studies is that they focus almost exclusively on industrial
pollution control costs. For a summary of limitations of different studies, see Congress of
the United States, Office of Technology Assessment (OTA), Trade and Environment,
Conflicts and Opportunities, Appendix E. OTA-BP-ITE-94, US Government Printing
Office, Washington, DC, May 1992.
158 René Vossenaar
Unilateral measures
A major concern in the area of PPMs is that making access to the do-
mestic market of the importing country subject to compliance with
unilaterally determined PPM standards can easily result in protection-
ism and could undermine the WTO multilateral trading system.12 As
mentioned above, so long as there are no transboundary environmen-
tal effects, the environment of the importing country will not be af-
fected by PPMs used in the exporting country. In these cases, protec-
tion of the importing country’s domestic environment does not require
that products imported into that country meet its own product-related
PPM standards.
In some cases, unilateral measures are used to deal with issues of
global environmental concern. However, the United Nations Confer-
11
See, e.g., Commission on Sustainable Development, fourth session, Decision 4/1 on
Trade, Environment and Sustainable Development, para. 4.c: Commission on Sustainable
Development, Report on the Fourth Session, E/1996/28 and E/CN.17/1996/38.
12
The Business and Industry Advisory Committee of the OECD (BIAC) has observed that
‘Unilateral trade measures imposed on the basis of the process or production method used
to make a product are unacceptable. Such measures assume that importing countries have
the right to pass judgements on the domestic policies of their trading partners, and to impose
their judgements through trade instruments. There is no limit to the extent to which such
unilateral measures could be used because no two countries have (nor should they
necessarily be expected to have) equivalent environmental policies and standards in all
areas. The use of trade measures in such circumstances would tend to lead to their
imposition for any difference between national environmental policies and standards (not to
mention policies in the areas of labour, tax competition law, etc.) and to rapid decline in
international law.’ Business and Industry Advisory Committee of the OECD, BIAC
Statement to the Special Session of the OECD Environmental Policy Committee, Paris, 7–8
December 1993, p. 3.
PPMs: sizing up the issues from the South 161
13
With regard to unilateral measures, in its report the Appellate Body mentioned some
issues that it had not been required to address. First, it did not address the question whether
there is an implied jurisdictional limitation in Article XX(g), and, if so, the nature or extent
of that limitation. Second, it did not address the question whether the importing country
would have been entitled to adopt unilateral measures in case efforts to achieve international
cooperation were not successful.
162 René Vossenaar
14
In this context, Australia, in its submission to the Appellate Body, argued that the United
States had refused to certify Australia even though Australia’s sea turtle conservation regime
‘extends well beyond protecting turtles from shrimping nets and includes cooperative
programs with the shrimp industry to limit turtle bycatch’.
15
United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, WT/DS58/
AB/R at 164, 12 October 1998.
PPMs: sizing up the issues from the South 163
Market forces
Apart from the question of trade rules, PPM-related standards may play
a role in overall consumer acceptance of a product. Both product and
process-related environmental ‘virtues’ of a product may become fac-
tors of competitiveness in environmentally conscious consumer mar-
kets.
Thus, producers may incur costs for environmental investments be-
cause of demands arising in export markets. For example, it is believed
that part of the investment costs incurred by Canadian and Swedish
pulp and paper industries are a result of consumer pressure in Europe,
particularly Germany, for chlorine-free paper, and are not solely a re-
sult of higher standards.16
Environmentally related consumer preferences in overseas markets
may have effects on processes and raw material usage in developing
countries. Retailers may give instructions to their suppliers on how a
product should be made or which raw materials should be used. For
example, a number of Turkish exporters reported that importing com-
panies require detailed information on the manufacturing process and/
or undertake plant inspections.17
More research is needed to analyse the true extent to which the
above mentioned factors affect market access and competitiveness.
Consumers in OECD countries may show a preference for specific
PPMs favouring domestic products over imported ones. For example,
if sustainable forest management is an important element in the choice
of wooden furniture in OECD countries, then temperate wood prod-
ucts may automatically be substituted for tropical wood products.
16
See OTA, Trade, Technology and the Environment, p. 199.
17
Celik Aruoba (Research on Trade and Environment Linkages in Turkey), ‘Report I:
Environment–Trade Link: Impact of Environmental Regulations and Standards in European
and North American Markets on Turkish Exports’, in V. Jha, A. Markandya and R.
Vossenaar (eds), Reconciling Trade and Environment, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham,
forthcoming.
164 René Vossenaar
Subsidies
Direct financial assistance provided by governments to producers in
order to assist them in complying with environmental regulations is
considered a subsidy by the GATT. However, under the Uruguay Round
Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures, some environ-
mental subsidies are exempted from the general rule that ‘specific’
subsidies are ‘actionable’. Assistance made available to firms for the
adaptation of their existing facilities to conform with new environmen-
tal regulations which results in a greater financial burden is ‘non-
actionable’, provided that certain other conditions are met.
Some subsidies eliminate external costs or capture environmental
benefits, and these should not be actionable, in principle, under the
GATT.22 Developing countries may have special needs in the field of
subsidies; for example, it may be worth exploring the needs of small
and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in developing countries. How-
ever, because of competing financial priorities, developing countries
often cannot provide compensating subsidies for environmental stan-
dards.
22
C.S. Pearson and R. Repetto, ‘Reconciling Trade and Environment: the Next Steps’,
paper prepared for the Trade and Environment Committee of the US Environmental
Protection Agency, 1992.
PPMs: sizing up the issues from the South 167
23
UNCTAD and the Government of Norway, op. cit.
24
For example, in the United States the Overseas Private Investment Corporation has
proposed an environmental Investment Fund to stimulate environmental investment in
developing countries. The Energy Policy Act of 1992 directs the Secretary of Energy,
through AID, ‘to create a technology transfer program aimed at reducing the US trade
deficit through the export of innovative environmental technologies’. The Export
Enhancement Act of 1992 seeks to encourage exports of environmental goods and services.
See Pearson and Repetto, Reconciling Trade op. cit.
168 René Vossenaar
25
WT/CTE/W/67.
PPMs: sizing up the issues from the South 169
largely on the issue of ‘dirty industry migration’ (see above). More re-
cently, discussions have focused on the issue of technologies and
management practices associated with FDI. A widely held view is
that TNCs tend to apply the environmental standards and manage-
ment practices of the corporation or the home country, which often go
beyond local legal requirements in the host country. According to an-
other hypothesis, however, trade liberalization and FDI can at times
result in the transfer (to developing countries) of technologies and
products that have become ‘obsolete’ as a result of increasingly strin-
gent environmental policies and regulations in developed countries.
An important question concerns the extent to which foreign investors
have contributed sufficient leadership with respect to fulfilling local
and global environmental targets.
In many respects, the answer to these questions depends on the ex-
tent to which TNCs have devised environmental management policies,
procedures and practices for their subsidiaries in developing countries
(labelled as ‘cross-border environmental management’). UNCTAD,
through its Division on Investment, Technology and Enterprise Devel-
opment (DITE), jointly with the Department of Intercultural Communi-
cation and Management (DICM) of the Copenhagen Business School
(CBS), is carrying out a project comprising a number of case studies on
cross-border environmental management of TNCs.26
Building on these activities, UNCTAD is initiating a new project
which focuses on the contribution that investment could make to
achieving the objectives of selected multilateral environmental agree-
ments, as well as the role that TNCs could play in disseminating high
environmental standards and environmental management systems to
local companies in developing countries. The emphasis is on technol-
ogy dissemination and spillovers on host countries. Building on the
findings of the DANIDA project, this project focuses on MEAs. The
government of Germany is providing funding to the project. The Ger-
man government is also funding a parallel project, executed by the In-
stitute for Environmental Management and Business Administration at
the European Business School in Germany.
26
This project is funded by the Danish International Development Administration (DANIDA).
170 René Vossenaar
28
Some have expressed the view that concerns about the possible discriminatory character
of PPM-based standards could be magnified, depending on the degree of patent protection
of specific technologies.
174 René Vossenaar
vided that PPMs are also useful in the context of the environmental and
developmental conditions in the country of production.
Future work on PPMs could include analysis of the relationship be-
tween PPMs and trade, including consideration of trade principles
which could ensure that the application of PPM-based instruments
does not result in arbitrary discrimination or unjustified restrictions on
trade. A second issue is whether international standards developed for
instruments and measures that extend to PPMs, such as the ISO 14000
series, could provide sufficient guarantees to this effect. A third issue
that arises is this: if there is a consensus on the need to move towards
greater convergence of PPMs, what would be an appropriate mecha-
nism, and what would be the role of FDI, taking into account the inter-
ests of all parties with different environmental endowments and at dif-
ferent levels of development?
Reassessing ‘like products’
Konrad von Moltke
Introduction
The issue of process and production methods (PPMs) in the trade re-
gime has vexed the environmental community since the first Tuna/
Dolphin panel claimed that distinctions between products based on
their production methods were not permitted under the GATT. The reason
for its distress is straightforward: an open trading system, which does
not provide for distinctions between products produced sustainably
and those produced unsustainably, is unacceptable from an environ-
mental perspective.
Unless the issue of PPMs is resolved in a reasonable manner, the en-
vironmental community will ultimately oppose trade liberalization. It
is up to those interested in trade policy to decide whether they are will-
ing to pursue their goals against environmental opposition – in es-
sence, whether they can persuade voters in democratic societies that
the economic benefits they promise outweigh not only the inevitable
economic costs to those who do not enjoy comparative advantage, but
also the risks to the environment, and to communities.
ucts is in many ways the linchpin of the GATT/WTO system. Its two
central principles, most favoured nation treatment (MFN) and national
treatment, are critically dependent on this concept. The key passages
in the GATT read as follows:
that all products currently being traded with IPR protection should be
traded as commodities, i.e. to a single, universally accepted specifica-
tion.
This brief discussion is not the occasion to discuss the role of com-
modity markets in pricing the environment or in promoting (or ob-
structing) the internalization of environmental costs in products traded
on international markets. This is a matter requiring much more research
and public debate than it has received to date.
missible, but whether they are needed – and, if they are needed, what
rules should apply.
The importance of PPMs for the attainment of sustainability has not
yet been conclusively demonstrated. The significance of PPMs in this
context is highly intuitive; nevertheless it resides on a critical notion
related to the characteristics of commodity markets: namely that with-
out certain PPMs producers of commodities will be confronted with an
invidious choice: degrade the environment or lose market share.
This is a restatement of one of the most persistent of all ideas in the
environment–trade debate: namely, that rules are required to avoid the
creation of ‘pollution havens’. No clear evidence has yet been ad-
duced to show that pollution havens exist. In part, this is attributable to
the fact that researchers have been asking the wrong question: is there
any risk of a general move of production from ‘high-regulation’ to
‘low-regulation’ jurisdictions? Enterprises with significant profit mar-
gins, in particular those benefiting from IPRs, will not make location
decisions based on the cost of environmental protection. The reasons
are complex, ranging from the modest cost of environmental mea-
sures, relative to other factors of production, to the importance of prox-
imity to major markets to the need to protect a brand’s image. On the
other hand, there is some evidence that the production of commodities,
and to a lesser degree of certain commodity manufactures, has shifted
away from high-regulation jurisdictions to those with lower regulation.
The reasons are again complex, ranging from the availability of higher-
value uses of scarce environmental resources in locations close to the
value added centres of the world, to the resistance of highly urbanized
societies in Europe and Japan to further destruction of the landscape,
and to the availability of cheap labour for labour-intensive phases of
the product chain. With these few observations, we are again in the
relatively unexplored area of commodity production and the envi-
ronment, which also happens to be the prime domain for environ-
mental PPMs.
Interestingly, viewing the TRIPS Agreement for what it is – an agree-
ment on the application of certain PPMs – provides some guidelines
on how to address PPMs in the trading system. It is true that national
environmental protection measures are the first step towards any inter-
182 Konrad von Moltke
The Shrimp/Turtle dispute has changed the face of the issue of process
and production methods (PPMs) and trade. There are still problems
with the outcome. The final decision went the wrong way in the end for
the environmental community, and that will create political problems
in the United States for the Administration’s efforts to secure ‘fast
track’ negotiating authority, as well as for the WTO more generally in
other parts of the globe.
Shrimp/Turtle was also the irrefutable proof that the multilateral trad-
ing system has to, and is beginning to, come to terms with the issues
surrounding processing and production methods. The Appellate Body
found that the US measure requiring the fitting of turtle excluder de-
vices (TEDs) to shrimp nets did in principle qualify it for exception
under Article XX(g), which means that discrimination based on PPMs
is acceptable under WTO rules. The Appellate Body ruling also began
to come to terms with other civil society concerns about the WTO in
that it used a fairly liberal interpretation of WTO rules to accept unso-
licited amicus briefs from non-governmental organizations. Third, the
Appellate Body began to enact something that first appeared in the
Venezuela Gasoline Appellate Body report, in beginning to take ac-
count of other public international law; in particular, the Appellate
Body took account of multilateral environmental agreements (MEAs).
The World Wide Fund For Nature (WWF) was among the NGOs that
submitted amicus briefs to this panel, and we called for these three
things to be done. We also called for the measure to be upheld given
the endangered status of turtles and their protection under MEAs; but
the Appellate Body still struck the measure down on the grounds that it
was arbitrary and unjustifiable on seven separate counts.
That is a lot of hurdles to get over before a trade measure can be held
compatible with WTO rules. Some of the hurdles look like reasonable
ones, others may be construed as less reasonable. To take one ex-
184 Charles Arden-Clarke
ample, the Appellate Body in the Shrimp/Turtle case found that the
United States gave more technical assistance to some countries than to
others, and that amounted to unfair discrimination. It is important to be
careful in assessing the implications of this interpretation: presumably,
if the United States had given no technical assistance to anyone, it
would not have failed on that hurdle. There are other important ele-
ments too. The Appellate Body did not look at the question of whether
or not the US measure was a ‘disguised restriction on trade’; and it
pointed to the fact that the measure was ‘coercive in intent and effect’
without saying whether that might amount to a test that would have to
be met by any future measures.
The core of the problem with PPMs arises when they result in trans-
boundary and/or global effects. I would never advocate unilateral trade
measures as a tool of first resort, but Shrimp/Turtle came close to present-
ing a factual situation where they could and should be allowed as a last
resort – an endangered species being pushed much closer to extinction
by a clearly identified threat, which the technology required by the mea-
sure could reduce. Those points at least were recognized by the panel.
Better adherence to existing MEAs is also needed. One of the most
interesting points that came out of the Shrimp/Turtle case was a foot-
note which noted that the country with the worst record on signature
and ratification of MEAs out of the five countries involved in the dis-
pute was the United States. Some countries are setting themselves up
as environmental policemen, but that role is not necessarily reflected in
their signature of the multilateral legal instruments that exist for the
protection of the environment. This is something that governments,
NGOs and civil society as a whole must address.
The question now is, how can the WTO evolve further? There seem
to be two ways for it to evolve. One is through the dispute settlement
process. Dispute settlement in the WTO on trade and environment mat-
ters has improved fairly steadily since the first Tuna/Dolphin Panel
back in 1991, through the second Tuna/Dolphin Panel and the Auto-
mobile Tax dispute in 1994, and on to the Venezuela Gasoline Appel-
late Body ruling in 1996. Dispute settlement has been getting better
from an environmental perspective, and, while I hope that Shrimp/
Turtle is not the peak of that trend, it is the peak so far.
PPMs: the impact of the Shrimp/Turtle dispute 185
The second way for the WTO to evolve is through renegotiation and
reinterpretation of WTO rules, and this is still likely to be necessary. If
we settle these things purely through a dispute settlement process,
which is a very closed process, it is risky. These issues will need to be
settled, and they will need to be settled in the open. PPMs – the most
controversial subject, which has destroyed consensus in the WTO on a
regular basis – will have to be addressed as a central and systemic issue.
More than that, it will need to be mainstreamed into the WTO. It is not
just a question of dealing with it in the context of individual specific is-
sues: any deal on PPMs has to be part of a bigger trade deal. This may
sound like an argument for the Millennium Round. It is not: it is an argu-
ment for mainstreaming environment in the next Millennium Round.
This brings me to the proposed High Level Meeting on trade and
environment. This is a litmus test of government commitment: whether
or not that High Level Meeting takes place; whether it is about sub-
stance; and whether there is serious preparation beforehand. The High
Level Meeting should be preparation for mainstreaming the environ-
ment, including the PPM issue.
I agree that the environmental community will also have to articulate
better what we want on PPMs, and that the process of securing this will
have to be an open and inclusive one. We also need a real-life discus-
sion with real-life issues that involve both the World Trade Organiza-
tion and existing MEAs, because otherwise the discussion will become
very oblique and abstruse. Shrimp/Turtle was just that. We could do
worse than take the example offered by the Shrimp/Turtle case as a
starting point from which to begin building lasting solutions. It has all
the elements. It is about PPMs and it involves MEAs and the WTO. It
does not perhaps involve MEAs as much as it should have, but that is a
question of political will for governments, and also a job for NGOs.
But we have to do this outside the WTO; it has to be done in a forum
that encompasses trade, environment and development. We need to
escape the ‘WTO decides’ factor, and we also need to escape the na-
tional-level ‘chill factor’ that WTO rules apply to the development of
effective environmental policies.
Finally, we also need a multi-stakeholder approach. In the case of
shrimps and turtles, we do not want just the vociferous NGOs: we also
186 Charles Arden-Clarke
want the fishermen whose livelihoods are affected by the trade em-
bargo, and who depend on a healthy marine eco-system for those live-
lihoods. We need the appellants in the case and the respondents; we
need the United States and the four countries involved in the dispute.
We need anybody else who is interested as a third party. We need rep-
resentatives of the WTO and of the MEAs. We need the environment
and the development NGOs, and we need the independent experts
who often have a key role to play, because even NGOs can have
vested interests.
Conflict Resolution in the World Trade
Organization
Introduction
The World Trade Organization is dedicated to improving the standard
of living of people in its member states by establishing legally binding
rules to liberalize international trade. WTO rules affect trade in goods,
services and the trade-related aspects of intellectual property rights.
The structures of liberalized trade, in turn, often impact on the environ-
ment. When they do, non-governmental organizations (NGOs) may
attempt to sway public opinion so as to limit the measure’s negative
impacts on the environment.
Environmental protection rules are dedicated to conserving resources
and maintaining the health of the natural environment and its inhabit-
ants. Environmental rules affect the use of resources, the consumption
of products and services, and the production of services. In addition,
however, environmental rules sometimes affect the trade of goods, ser-
vices and the trade-related aspects of intellectual property rights. When
they do, conflicts often arise, and, in the absence of other formal dis-
pute settlement forums, WTO Members often turn to the processes
contained within the WTO Understanding on the Rules and Procedures
Governing the Settlement of Disputes (DSU) to protect their rights un-
der the various WTO Agreements.
Conflict resolution and dispute settlement are becoming increasingly
important at this intersection of the trade and environment fields. In
part this is due to the public’s attention being captured on this problem
more than on any other topic relating to the WTO. In part it is because
the severity of environmental problems is becoming more pressing in
the developed as well as in the developing nations of the world, and
188 T. Cottier and K. N. Schefer
1
See Sanford E. Gaines, ‘Rethinking Environmental Protection, Competitiveness, and
International Trade’, U.Chic.Legal F. 231, 238–48 (1997) (presenting a short history of the
attitudinal changes as regards trade and environment), and especially 231 (‘With specific
reference to the environment and international trade, Agenda 21 contains the affirmation that
environment and trade policies should be mutually supportive’ [citing Agenda 2 1, UN Doc
A/CONF 151126 (1992)] but neither before nor after Rio have governments or analysts
been able to agree on how (or even whether) such a mutually supportive relationship can be
achieved’); David A. Wirth, ‘The Rio Declaration on Environment and Development: Two
Steps Forward and One Back, or Vice Versa’, 29 Ga.L.Rev. 599 (1995) (fearing that
economic development necessarily entails environmental damage).
190 T. Cottier and K. N. Schefer
The traditional idea that trade and environment were inevitably at odds
with one another gave way in the late 1980s to the teachings of those
who emphasized the compatibility of the two systems: trade, they said,
leads to increased growth, which in turn leads to wealth, which in turn
leads to an interest in environmental protection. Environmental rules,
moreover, need not collide with the principles of non-discrimination
and economic liberalization enshrined in the WTO (then GATT) Agree-
ments. A decade later, scholars began to question this new thinking.2
Today, while the trade community generally still adheres to the theory
of trade and environmental compatibility, many environmentalists are
rediscovering the potential for conflict: they emphasize that, although
it may indeed be true that the goals of trade and environmental protec-
tion do not generally conflict in practice, there is an inherent potential
for conflict between the two that needs to be addressed (in part at least
because of an inability to translate the value of a healthy environment
into quantifiable economic units).3
The WTO officially supports the idea that trade and environment
goals are mutually supportive. Whether or not this is a correct view at
the level of philosophical fundamentals of the two systems will not be
further analysed here. Practical experience would indicate that there is
a potential for certain of the rules of the two systems to conflict, but
that this conflict is not intrinsic to all of the rules.
What is important to the immediate issue of trade–environment con-
flict resolution is that almost every agreement within the WTO system
contains exceptions from the trade liberalization rules in order to pro-
vide for Members’ efforts to protect the environment, thus supposedly
lowering the likelihood of direct conflicts between trade rules and en-
2
See, e.g., Paul Brietzke, ‘Insurgents in the New International Law’, 13 Wis.Int’l L.J. 1
(1994) (discussing the different perspectives of ‘classical’ international law views and the
views of ‘insurgents’, ‘without lapsing into the polemics of the conflict models that rival
those of a consensus’); Jeffrey L. Dunoff, ‘Rethinking International Trade’, 19 U. Pa. J.
Int’l Econ. L. 347 (1998) (examining ‘linkage’ issues, such as trade and the environment,
and concluding that a new way of thinking about these issues must be developed).
3
To borrow a term from international trade expert John H. Jackson, this is the ‘clash of
cultures’ idea. See John H. Jackson, ‘Greening the GATT: Trade Rules and Environmental
Policy’ in James Cameron, Paul Demaret and Damien Geradin, eds., Trade & the
Environment: The Search for Balance, Chapter 2 (Cameron May, London, 1994).
Conflict resolution: assessing the story so far 191
7
(cont)
... Sanitary and phytosanitary measures shall not be applied in a manner which would
constitute a disguised restriction on international trade.
4. Sanitary or phytosanitary measures which conform to the relevant provisions of this
Agreement shall be presumed to be in accordance with the obligations of the Member… in
particular the provisions of Article XX(b) [GATT]’.
8
United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, WT/DS58/
AB/R at para. 116 (12 October 1998) (‘Maintaining, rather than undermining, the
multilateral trading system is necessarily a fundamental and pervasive premise underlying
the WTO Agreement, but it is not a right or an obligation, nor is it an interpretive rule….’)
9
See United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, WT/
DS58/AB/R para. 7.42 (15 May 1998) (‘While the Preamble confirms that environmental
considerations are important for the interpretation of the WTO Agreement, the central focus
of that agreement remains the promotion of economic development through trade; and the
provisions of the GATT are essentially turned toward liberalization of access to markets on
a nondiscriminatory basis.’)
10
See United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, WT/
DS58/AB/R at para. 185 (12 October 1998) (‘We have not decided that the protection and
preservation of the environment is of no significance to the Members of the WTO. Clearly,
it is. We have not decided that the sovereign nations that are Members of the WTO cannot
adopt effective measures to protect endangered species.... Clearly, they can and should. And
we have not decided that sovereign states should not act together bilaterally, plurilaterally or
multilaterally, either within the WTO or in other international fora, to protect endangered
species or to otherwise protect the environment. Clearly, they should and do.’)
Conflict resolution: assessing the story so far 193
11
See, e.g., the new links installed by the WTO on its Internet home page (www.wto.org)
for the benefit of NGOs and the wider public, as well as various speeches by General
Director Renato Ruggiero on the issues of transparency and relations with civil society.
194 T. Cottier and K. N. Schefer
the two products, and whether the products have ‘essentially the same
physical characteristics’.12 This has two implications for trade and en-
vironment problems: first, the chemical or genetic composition of the
product at issue must differ from that of the domestic or other foreign
product in order for an environmental law to distinguish the treatment
given to the product at issue and remain WTO-compatible; and, sec-
ond, the environmental law may not distinguish between treatment of
‘like products’ based on the method of production of the product. The
WTO’s approach to the latter, the so-called process and production
methods or PPM problem, is to consider only the product itself as a
product, and to reject the use of trade barriers to protect a different
product. As we will see, however, the PPM issue has been downplayed
in the most recent Appellate Body decision in this area.
Finally, the structure of the commitments in the GATS makes the use
of environmental protection measures aimed at trade in services poten-
tially more valuable than does the exception in GATT for environmen-
tal barriers to trade in goods. Unlike in their goods sector obligations,
WTO Members may attach conditions to their liberalizing concessions
in the field of trade in services. These conditions, presumably, could
include requirements to meet environmental standards in the produc-
tion of the service as well as in the marketing or even in the consump-
tion of the service – whether in the Member’s territory or outside of it.
scrutiny. Therefore, these are certainly not the only possible WTO–
environment conflicts, and, as discussed above, there may be environ-
mentally friendly changes in the WTO’s attitude to such conflicts in the
not so distant future.
Import prohibitions
First, there are environmental laws that prohibit the importation of cer-
tain environmentally unfriendly goods or services in accordance with a
multilateral agreement regulating such trade. An example would be a
prohibition on the importation of a particular endangered species (or a
good produced from the parts of an endangered species) listed in An-
nex 1 of the Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species
(CITES). Although such a law would violate the GATT prohibition on
import restrictions,13 it would certainly be seen as a legitimate excep-
tion under the provisions of GATT Article XX. By virtue of the pres-
ence of the species on a multilaterally approved list such as the Annex
to CITES, the restriction would almost automatically be considered
‘necessary’ to protect human, animal or plant life or health’,14 or ‘relat-
ing to’ the conservation of an exhaustible natural resource.15 In addi-
tion, the chapeau of Article XX requiring that the measure not be a
discriminatory restriction or disguised protectionism would be similarly
fulfilled.
A modification of this example would be an environmental law that
restricts the importation of a product or service on the basis that that
product or service is environmentally unfriendly, but without regard to
a multilateral environmental agreement. Even if the Member also pro-
hibits the production of the product domestically, such a law is much
more likely to be found to violate a Member’s WTO obligations than
the first example. This is due to the emphasis given to the chapeau of
Article XX and the concept of multilateralism that has become domi-
13
See GATT Article XI.
14
GATT Article XX(b). Virtually the same exception is found in the General Agreement on
Trade in Services (GATS) Article XIV(b).
15
GATT Article XX(g). The GATS has no equivalent provision.
196 T. Cottier and K. N. Schefer
nant in the opinions of the panels and Appellate Body.16 In the absence
of formal multilateral agreements establishing near unanimity on what
constitutes an environmental problem, and on the ‘correct’ approach to
solving the problem, Members will face an uphill battle to get the WTO
to approve the implementation of its trade-restricting regulation.
If the law treats domestic producers and foreign producers differ-
ently, this is almost certain to be found to amount to a disguised restric-
tion on trade, and therefore to be incompatible with the Member’s WTO
obligations.17 Thus, a US Clean Air Act provision that omitted the pos-
sibility for foreign gas refiners to establish their own baselines was
found WTO-illegal despite the Appellate Body’s decision that the mea-
sure did relate to the conservation of a natural resource (clean air).18
16
The Appellate Body’s decision in the recent dispute regarding US regulations limiting
shrimp imports based on the injury to turtles from the fishing methods used finds the
measures an unexcused violation of US GATT obligations based on the chapeau of Article
XX. The Appellate Body found that the US unilateral imposition of a policy requiring the
use of particular fishing methods and the implementation of the law were arbitrary. United
States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, WT/DS58/AB/R, at
para. 184.
17
Although different treatment for like products may be permitted as long as conditions of
competition are not unequal, the difference in treatment raises the suspicion that it had the
aim of discriminating or disadvantaging one group of producers. See United States –
Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline, WT/DS2/AB/R (20 May 1996),
at DD98A/20: ‘There is, or course, no textual basis for requiring identical treatment of
domestic and imported products, Indeed, where there is identity of treatment – constituting
real, not merely formal, equality of treatment – it is difficult to see how inconsistency with
Article 111:4 of GATT would have arisen in the first place. On the other hand, if no
restrictions on domestically produced like products are imposed at all, and all limitations are
placed upon imported products alone, the measure … would simply be naked discrimination
for protecting locally produced goods.’ See also EC Measures Concerning Meat and Meat
Products (Hormones), WT/DS26/AB/R, and WT/DS48/AB/R (16 January 1998), para.
240 (explaining that arbitrarily different sanitary and phytosanitary standards are violations
of the Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures if the
difference in fact discriminates between WTO Members or constitutes a disguised
restriction on trade).
18
United States – Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline, WT/DS2/AB/
R (20 May 1996).
Conflict resolution: assessing the story so far 197
Environmental subsidies
A third category of potential trade–environment conflict is that of a
WTO Member offering competitive advantages to environmentally
friendly products or services. Environmental subsidies – monies given
to a producer for using the presumably more expensive methods of
production in order to protect the environment – could theoretically
cause a distortion in the conditions of competition, as the products sub-
sidized are not physically different from non-subsidized products.25
Thus, a question arises as to whether the competitive advantage is war-
ranted. No such case has yet been addressed in the WTO, but if or
when one is, it will require renewed investigation into how to define a
‘like product’ (under the GATT) or a ‘like service supplier’ (under the
GATS) as well as an examination of whether the offsetting of the in-
creased costs of environmentally safe production methods through
subsidies is fair, recognizing that other producers to a very large ex-
tent are able to simply externalize their pollution costs.
Related to this issue, what if a Member used environmental stan-
dards – either positively or negatively – in its treatment of foreign in-
vestments or to prevent foreign service suppliers from establishing a
commercial presence in its territory? Although it would clearly go
25
There is a provision under the Subsidies Agreement that allows a Member State to offer
a one-time subsidy to an industry in order to assist the industry in complying with a new
environmental protection regulation. (Subsidy Agreement, Article 8.2(c)). The use of
subsidies, including environmental subsidies, under investigation is particularly important
for the service sectors. See GATS Article XV; Decision on Trade in Services and the
Environment, in WTO Secretariat, The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade
Negotiations: Legal Texts 457–458, Geneva, 1995. See also ‘WTO Completes Framework
for Environmental, Regional and R&D Subsidies’, WTO Focus, No. 32, p. 2 (July 1998)
(reporting that the WTO Committee for Subsidies and Countervailing Duties has
established rules to govern binding arbitration in the area of environmental, regional and
research and development subsidies).
Conflict resolution: assessing the story so far 199
27
Ibid. at para. 253 (l).
28
Ibid.
29
Ibid. at para. 253(h)
30
Ibid. at para. 172.
31
The Salmon case addressed a ‘typical’ use of sanitary measures rather than one relating
to biotechnology. See Australia – Measures Affecting Importation of Salmon, WT/DS18/R
(12 June 1998); WT/DS18/AB/R (20 October 1998). Here again, however, there seems to
be a more deferential attitude of the panel and Appellate Body to a Member’s use of trade
restrictions for health than there is under the GATT environmental exceptions. In Salmon,
the Appellate Body found that there was no risk assessment made by the Australian
government, as required by Article 5.1 of the SPS Agreement, and thus the import
prohibition on fresh, frozen or chilled salmon violated Article 5.1: WT/DS18/AB/R at para.
136. In analysing the compatibility of the import prohibition with Article 5.6 of the SPS
Agreement, the Appellate Body comes to no definite conclusions (owing to a lack of
sufficient fact-finding by the panel on this issue), but asserts that the Member itself may
determine the level of protection it desires. Consequently, the WTO review of the measures
used to achieve such a goal is limited to determining whether they are the least trade-
restrictive measures to achieve that level of protection: the level of protection itself is not to
be questioned. Even a zero-risk level is permissible. See WT/DS18/AB/R at paras. 193–213.
Conflict resolution: assessing the story so far 201
32
The future of the trade–environment discussion is evident through further WTO
instruments, namely the Decision on Trade and Environment and the Decision on Trade in
Services and the Environment. Formally organized discussions such as the one that took
place in mid-March 1998 also push the trade–environment agenda forward.
202 T. Cottier and K. N. Schefer
Introduction
This short paper addresses the ‘how’ of dispute settlement. What can
be done to change the way the dispute settlement system operates in
order better to accommodate environment and development issues? To
be even more precise, what kinds of environment and development
issues are currently not adequately accommodated in the dispute settle-
ment system?
very useful for future cases. The way Article XX was interpreted is ac-
ceptable, although too much remains loaded onto the chapeau – and I
do not quite understand why the chapeau has anything particular to
say about MEAs.
The irony here is that for many years I have argued for a technical fix
in Article XX which would involve adding a reference to multilateral
environmental agreements in a sub-paragraph, possibly attached to an
Understanding which would explain why reference to the MEAs is rel-
evant and how it could be used to settle disputes – including, for ex-
ample, a definition of what a ‘multilateral environmental agreement’ is.
However, since WTO cases have loaded more responsibility onto the
chapeau of Article XX, we have now to pay attention to that line of
reasoning. It is not possible to solve the problem technically by adding
a new paragraph to Article XX which relates to MEAs. We need some-
thing that informs the interpretation of the chapeau as well. That might
argue for a separate set of negotiations related specifically to that ques-
tion. There is no simple way of curing the problem relating to MEAs by
an amendment of one of the sub-paragraphs of Article XX now that the
reasoning in Shrimp/Turtle is established.
stage it is fair enough to put in facts that are of relevance, but at the
Appellate Body stage only legal arguments should be permitted. In
addition, there is a value in creating what in the UK we call ‘your day
in court’. People who are involved with disputes really want to say to
someone what it is that makes them angry. They want a platform to
say: ‘This is my view; you have to listen to it.’ I would be in favour of
creating within the panel process – and also within the Appellate Body
process, for an even shorter period of time – a ‘day in court’, an oppor-
tunity for NGOs or indeed business associations to come along and
present their arguments very briefly – if you cannot make your main
point in 15 minutes, you are not really worth listening to. The US Su-
preme Court has very tight time limits; the House of Lords in the UK
has very tight time limits. So you have an opportunity to come and
make your point, but it is a limited-time opportunity and you organize
your public relations and your media coverage around the debate and
get some publicity for it. The panel is informed, it comes to understand
this weird counter-view that it has never really been confronted with
face-to-face, but at a certain point that is it – your time is up; the pro-
ceedings continue.
There are some other changes that also need to be made in order to
make the process more open and accountable generally, but with par-
ticular benefit to environment and development organizations.
First, panel and Appellate Body reports are far too long. It is just not
sensible to be sending out 400-page reports to people around the world,
even if you can get them on the Internet – in itself a very significant in-
novation in opening up access to information, and one which the NGO
community pushed for and achieved. We have to stop governments
requiring that all of their arguments be repeated faithfully in the deci-
sions of both the panel and the Appellate Body. It is simply not neces-
sary. If governments want you to know what they have said, then they
should publish it, making their arguments public as documents as soon
as they feel it is appropriate, and allowing panels and the Appellate
Body to make summaries.
I would like to see the system evolve to a point where judgments are
really nice, crisp, and written in plain English, so that people can un-
derstand why a technical trade rule that has been applied, and that af-
208 James Cameron
Introduction
During the 1990s, foreign direct investment (FDI) has come to play an
increasingly important role in providing India with sources of long-
term capital. Increasing levels of FDI also holds the promise of pro-
moting sustainable development in so far as it encourages the transfer
and harmonization of environmentally friendly technologies and prac-
tices across borders. In India it is not clear whether FDI and its associ-
ated transnational corporations (TNCs) have contributed sufficient
leadership in fulfilling local and global environmental targets.
In India, the principal emerging issues with respect to international
investment and the need for sustainable development focus first and
foremost on the incorporation of a large number of sectors and regions
that have not so far benefited from FDI; second, on fostering the posi-
tive role that TNCs could play in conjunction with national govern-
ments in achieving environmental goals; and, third, on ensuring that
the competition between states for FDI should not induce a race-to-the-
bottom approach. The national and state governments will increas-
ingly have to consider and weigh policies with a view to encouraging
and fostering healthy competition and avoiding policies that seek to
attract capital on the basis of lowest-common-denominator variables in
terms of health and environmental standards.
The role of FDI in the Indian economy has varied over time, largely
as a response to the changing perception and policies of the Indian
government. Of late, the increasing and important role of FDI has been
recognized by most political parties, both as a source of finance and,
more importantly, as a source of top-of-the-line technologies. While
there has been a move towards greater liberalization of FDI across the
212 Veena Jha
Environmental concerns
A number of environmental concerns have been voiced about the op-
erations of TNCs in India. NGOs believe that, given the high fiscal
deficit as a proportion of total GNP, the national government would be
reluctant to control the operations of TNCs, thus leading to ecological
disasters. The dominance of TNCs in environmentally harmful sectors
is also a matter of concern, as this could mean that a large proportion of
TNC investment in India would necessarily focus on these environ-
mentally sensitive sectors.
214 Veena Jha
Indian NGOs have also expressed concern about the depletion and
excessive use of India’s genetic resources by TNCs. As TNCs control
much of the world’s genetic seed stocks as well as financing the bulk
of biotechnology research worldwide, they can reap large financial re-
wards from patenting life forms in India.
Other concerns voiced by various stakeholders relate to resource
depletion caused by the scale of operation of TNCs, e.g. deep sea fish-
ing, and the transfer of environmentally harmful technologies and prod-
ucts. Still others that have recently come to the fore in the Indian context
relate to the implementation of multilateral environmental agreements
(MEAs). Some commentators have claimed that, though TNCs have
access to the right technologies, MEAs may be conferring double ad-
vantages by providing them with a captive market and monopoly
prices accruing from the use of patented technologies.2
4
I. Jaising, ‘Legal Let-Down’, in T.R. Chouhan et al., Bhopal: The Inside Story, Apex
Press, NY, and the Other India Press, Goa, India, 1994.
216 Veena Jha
Another case that has been publicized in the media concerns the
transfer of a hazardous technology which is banned for domestic use
in Norway. The controversial technology was a membrane cell plant
whose operations were shut down in Norway in 1992, under pres-
sure from environmental groups against the use of chlorine in pulp
bleaching. Norway has a national policy which targets organochlorine
chemicals and includes a provision that the technology in question be
reduced and ultimately eliminated. In addition, its international com-
mitments for the reduction and elimination of harmful chemicals, such
as the North Sea Ministerial Declarations of 1987 and 1990, should
have put natural restraints on the transfer of environmentally harmful
technologies. In a counter-claim, however, the Norwegian firm claimed
that the technology being sold to India was not the outdated variety,
and the intermediary (another multinational) through which the deal
had been effected claimed that it had not brokered the deal.6
Other cases that have been brought up by the media concern distilleries
for making alcohol. A number of these companies are foreign-owned,
and considerable scepticism has been expressed over claims by a distill-
ery called Kedia Castle Dellon that a distillery could be a ‘zero-pollution’
plant. A plan submitted by the company to the State Pollution Control
Board in Rajasthan claims that about 1,800 cubic metres of spent wash
from the distillery would be processed daily to produce cattle feed. About
90–95 per cent of the wash would be evaporated, leading to the claim that
effluents and waste water would not be let out onto neighbouring agricul-
tural land. Citizens’ groups have, however, raised questions as to how
much energy would be required to evaporate such large quantities of wa-
ter and where the spent wash would go in case of a shutdown of this
cattle-feed plant. They object to the granting of a ‘no objection’ certificate
without a proper environmental impact assessment. Apart from the
possible pollution by this plant, local residents are also worried about
possible groundwater depletion by water-guzzling distilleries.7
In another case, an Expert Panel held Century Rayon responsible for
11 deaths from the inhalation of toxic gases emanating from the re-
6
See P. Seema, ‘Norway Ships Banned Technology to India’, Telegraph, 1 April 1995.
7
A. Krishna, ‘Is Zero-pollution Distillery Really Possible?’, IED, 20 May 1995.
218 Veena Jha
joint venture companies for auto parts to help push quality and produc-
tivity concerns upstream. It has also pushed up the levels of fuel effi-
ciency so that competing cars are forced to adhere to higher fuel effi-
ciency standards.
13
See ‘MNCs to Enter Alternative Energy Sector’, Economic Times, 15 April 1995.
222 Veena Jha
products such as leather and textiles. These testing agencies are either
set up by multinationals or funded by them. Multinationals have also
taken the lead in manufacturing environmentally friendly substitutes to
azo dyes and for providing testing facilities for them. Most of these
substitutes and testing facilities, however, can be utilized only by large
firms as they are too expensive for small and medium-sized enterprises
which comprise about 70 per cent of the textile industry in India.14
In response to a ban on the use of azo dyes in Germany, several large
firms including TNCs carried out a detailed analysis of the chemical
components of the dyes used by them in order to judge their eco-
friendliness and to gauge the extent to which they were required to
find substitutes. Once this was established, they were able to persuade
the dyestuff manufacturers, also dominated by TNCs, to switch to en-
vironmentally friendly substitutes. In fact, within a year TNCs and
other Indian large firms had switched to environmentally friendly alter-
native dyestuffs.15
In both the leather and textiles sector, some TNCs have not only set
up common effluent treatment plants (CETs), but have also provided
consultancy services to local companies to set up CETs. These services
are beyond the economic capacity of the small and medium-sized en-
terprises that dominate production in both these sectors. In the leather
sector, however, environmental infrastructure is better established
locally than in the textiles sector. While testing for environment friend-
liness of products is carried out both by TNCs and by government-
sponsored agencies, often the waiting time for the latter is much longer
than that for the former, perhaps because of the much higher prices
charged by TNCs.16
Another example is that of NOCIL, an agro-chemical-producing
TNC which installed on environmental infrastructure following notifi-
cation by the Central Pollution Control Board that its environmental
standards did not meet the requirements. This firm has taken care to
14
See S. Das, The Differential Impacts of Environmental Policies on Small and Large
Enterprises in India – with special reference to the Textile and Clothing and Leather and
Footwear Sectors, report prepared for UNCTAD under project INT/92/A58 1996.
15
Ibid.
16
Ibid.
The role of FDI: the case of India 223
ensure that spills and wastes are minimized, as well as putting up R&D
efforts to overcome problems identified in maintaining and operating a
common effluent treatment plant. The company has established a well-
defined system for environmental management under the managing
director. The set-up is designed to emphasize a self-regulatory mecha-
nism. Following these changes the Central Pollution Control Board
gave its consent for its operation.17 Cooperating with authorities on the
setting of high environmental standards TNCs have had a much more
decisive influence in setting voluntary standards than mandatory envi-
ronmental standards. Examples of TNCs acting in collaboration with
national authorities are to be observed particularly in dyestuffs and in
refrigeration in India. Both these industries are dominated by TNCs.
In the dyestuff sector there are no statutory eco-standards. However,
European manufacturers of dyes and organic pigments have voluntar-
ily formed the Ecological and Technological Toxicological Associa-
tion of Dyes and Organic Pigments Manufacturers (ETAD), which
recommends certain standards for handling, packaging and labelling
dyestuffs. Although ETAD is a voluntary organization and does not
have the authority to enforce compliance, it is compulsory for all
ETAD members to adhere to ETAD’s guidelines and standards. It is
nevertheless believed that TNC affiliates of ETAD have been active in
getting governments to ban several benzidine-based dyestuffs that are
known to be carcinogenic. In India, too, it is believed that the members
of ETAD have cooperated actively with the Bureau of Indian Stan-
dards in obtaining this ban.18
In the pharmaceutical sector, a TNC called Biocon India adheres to
the detailed specification for eco-friendly pharmaceuticals laid down
by both the United States and the United Kingdom, and latterly these
specifications have been adopted by the Bureau of Indian Standards.
Guidelines on packaging and the use of the ‘recyclable’ symbol as well
17
See ‘Environmental Audit of NOCIL Agrochemicals conducted by the Central Pollution
Control Board’, Programme Objective Series, Probes/49/1992–3.
18
See V. Bharucha, ‘The Impact of Environmental Regulations and Standards set in
Foreign Markets on India’s Exports’, in V. Jha et al. (eds), Trade, Environment and
Sustainable Development: A South Asian Perspective, Macmillan Press, New York and
Basingstoke, 1997.
224 Veena Jha
19
See Das, Differential Impacts.
The role of FDI: the case of India 225
have virtually dominated the market for certifying that firms comply
with ISO 14001. Nearly 32 firms have obtained ISO 14001 certificates,
of which most are local firms. TNCs that were earlier involved in pre-
shipment inspections are now also certifying Indian firms against ISO
14001 standards. They also provide training and have organized vari-
ous seminars to promote the adoption of these standards by firms.
In addition, TNCs have required their suppliers, subcontractors and
vendors to adhere to ISO 14001. Auditing and other forms of training
are also provided by these TNCs. However, the rates charged by these
firms are approximately double those charged by the Bureau of Indian
Standards in granting ISO 14001 certification. The Bureau of Indian
Standards has so far certified only one firm versus the 30 odd certified
by TNCs. This difference can be attributed to several factors, including
the late entry of the Bureau of Indian Standards onto the certification
scene, the aggressive marketing strategies of the TNCs, and perhaps
the wider acceptability of TNC certification by buyers down the supply
chain.20
20
Information provided by the Bureau of Indian Standards.
226 Veena Jha
21
See FDI and the Environment: An Overview of the Literature, Note by the Secretariat,
OECD, Paris, 1997.
The role of FDI: the case of India 227
22
See V. Shiva and C. Alvares, ‘BJP on Swadeshi: the great U-turn’, in Third World
Network Features – India, Third World Network, Penang, 1998.
228 Veena Jha
Introduction
This paper considers the need for private-sector investment and man-
agement in the water sector.
The global players in the international water industry are principally
European companies – and it is no coincidence that in Europe it is en-
vironmental legislation that has been a central driver for private-sector
funding and operation. The paper examines some of the key driving
forces for future private-sector investment as well as the current state of
play, arguing that the private sector has a central role to play in ad-
dressing the need for potable water and sanitation in towns and cities in
developing economies.
Finally, the paper argues that, for private-sector involvement to work
effectively, independent regulation is needed to safeguard environ-
ment, public health and consumer interests at the same time as ensur-
ing an operating climate that encourages private-sector investment and
involvement.
Sources: David Owen; UNDP, Human Development Report 1998, Oxford University Press,
Oxford, 1998; World Bank, World Development Report 1998/99, Oxford University Press,
Oxford, 1998.
Estimates of the global market size for water and wastewater services
and hardware range from US$200 billion p.a. (US$33 per capita) to
US$300 billion p.a. (US$50 per capita). The figure is notoriously im-
precise, however, because of the extent of hidden subsidies and the
inefficiencies inherent in the traditional municipal and quasi-private-
sector nature of the industry.
Despite the market’s size (and US$100 billion being spent during the
World Bank’s recent ‘Water Decade’), the United Nations concluded in
1997 that 25 per cent of the world’s population are facing water short-
ages. This is set to rise to 66 per cent by 2025. Global water consump-
tion is rising by 2.5 per cent per year, twice the rate of population
growth, having risen sixfold this century.
Against this background, state-owned and state-operated water and
sewerage concerns are finding it increasingly difficult to maintain their
levels of service, let alone expand to meet increasing urbanization or to
improve service quality. As a result, private water vendor services pro-
The role of FDI: liberalization, privatization and the water sector 233
vide water of dubious quality at five to 65 times the cost of piped water,
owing to a lack of viable alternatives (Table 2). The urban population
of the less developed regions is set to grow from 0.81 billion in 1975 to
2.02 billion in 2000 and to 4.03 billion by 2025. By that date, the UN be-
lieves that 65 per cent of the world’s population will be directly affected
by water shortages. According to the Global Environmental Facility
(GEF), US$700 billion of capital spending is needed to provide a basic
level of water and sanitation services (such as access to piped water and a
lavatory connected to a sewer in every street) over the next ten years.1
Sources: David Owen; Water Utilities Data Book, Asian Development Bank, Manila, 1993;
UNDP, An Urbanising World, UNDP, Oxford, 1996.
It is also very easy for vested interests to attack privatized water ser-
vices. You never ‘notice’ your water or sewerage services when they
are functioning perfectly, and thus perfection is taken for granted as
the norm: anything less than perfection – including for example the
perceived threat of supply limitations as seen in Britain in 1995 – is an
outright failure. In some countries, this can be a good reason for pri-
vate-sector investors to concentrate on areas such as bulk water provi-
sion, so that the actual dealings with the public remain in municipal
hands.
One of the commonest political arguments against the privatization
of water and sewerage services is that it will mean that water will be too
costly for poorer people. But this tends to ignore the fact that under the
current arrangements it is the poorer people living in urban areas who
have to pay over the odds to water vendors for supplies of distinctly
dubious quality. In India, for example, it is common for poorer urban
households to pay 25 per cent of their income for water services under
municipal control or via water vendors.
In fact, people are willing to pay an economic price for water ser-
vices if it comes with guarantees of quality and availability. Pragmatic
pricing policies based upon charging more per unit of water for house-
holds who use water for non-essential purposes has made private water
provision both affordable and viable. Popular support exists for ad-
equate supplies of water and improved public health at an affordable
rate. Opposition is notable among better-off households who are loathe
to pay an economic price for piped water supplies for gardens, washing
The role of FDI: liberalization, privatization and the water sector 235
cars and non-essential household uses. The fact that these are also the
people with the most political influence means that the political picture
is often distorted.
Privatization can be managed in such a way that local sensibilities
are catered for. While the ‘asset-sale’ privatization model (e.g. Britain
in 1989) has many fiscal attractions, taking the water and sewerage
infrastructure out of public hands has proven politically contentious.
A series of intermediate privatization models (operation and mainte-
nance, build–operate–transfer, and concessional) allow private-sector
operation with public ownership of the assets. Furthermore, by being
responsible for bulk water provision or sewage treatment and disposal,
the private-sector player needs to deal only with the municipality and
not with the public. Political risk can be managed even in the more
challenging markets, and cost and service quality benefits can be de-
livered directly or indirectly.
entail direct contact with the public, while water distribution and sew-
erage do. The latter, especially when involving billing and making a
service economically viable (for example, World Bank financed pro-
jects had water fees covering 35 per cent of the average cost of its sup-
ply), are the most politically contentious. In the words of the ASQC (an
American service quality monitoring organization), ‘the more contact
a firm has with its customers, the more it has a chance to screw up’.
abilities. This is one of the reasons why managing assets (via a man-
agement company) can make more sense than owning them. For ex-
ample, following the 1997 privatization of Budapest’s sewerage sys-
tem, Générale des Eaux and Germany’s BWB own the management
company, which in turn owns 25 per cent of the asset company. The
majority of the latter company remains in the hands of the municipality.
Source: D.A.L. Owen, P. Hollobone and P. Wilde, Come On In, the Water’s Lovely, Panmure
Gordons, London 1998. See also D.A.L. Owen, World Water Review 1999, Masons, London,
forthcoming.
Sources: David Owen, Water Utilities Data Book, Asian Development Bank, Manila, 1993;
and Managing Water Resources to Meet Megacity Needs, Asian Development Banks, Manila,
1994. See also D.A.L Owen, World Water Review 1999, Masons, London, forthcoming.
Some 5 per cent of the global water and wastewater market are already
under private-sector control. But it would be wrong to assume that the
entire market is open to the private sector. For example, many con-
struction-related aspects of these markets are proving to be distinctly
unpalatable to private-sector service providers. In certain areas, provi-
sion of direct customer services (such as billing and metering) is liable
to expose a foreign company to local and nationalistic political con-
cerns.
Over the next decade, the addressable market, that is the market in-
volving privatization opportunities for municipal drinking water provi-
The role of FDI: liberalization, privatization and the water sector 239
Sources: Anglian Water International, Vivendi, and David Owen. See also D.A.L. Owen, P.
Hollobone, and P. Wilde, Making Waves Overseas, West LB, London, 1999, for revised data.
Source: D.A.L. Owen, P. Hollobone, and P. Wilde, Come On In, the Water’s Lovely, Panmure
Gordons, London, 1998; see also D.A.L. Owen, P. Hollobone, and P. Wilde, Making Waves
Overseas, West LB, London, 1999, for revised data.
Over the next two years, industry sources point to 50–70 million
people having their water and/or sewerage services privatized. This
number refers to services actively being prepared for privatization.
The underlying figure is likely to be at least as high over the next two
240 David Owen
decades. Major players such as Vivendi (Générale des Eaux) are com-
mitted to gaining at least 20 per cent of this market.
Introduction
From September 1995, when Frans Engering was elected chairman of
the MAI Negotiating Group, until April this year, when he stepped
down as chairman, I sat next to him when he conducted the meetings
of the Negotiating Group. The leadership of the Negotiating Group
was in the hands of a so-called Bureau, consisting of the chairman and
two vice-chairmen, one from the United States and one from Japan.
The Bureau met before each session of the Negotiating Group. One of
its main activities was to prepare the agenda for each session, and to
decide on the kind of documentation to be made available to the
group. I was the secretary of the Bureau. My work in these two and a
half years, and in fact the negotiation process as a whole, has been
greatly facilitated by the staff of the OECD Secretariat. Their profes-
sionalism, dedication and creativity has been truly impressive.
The negotiators’ failure fully to incorporate the environmental di-
mension from the start of the MAI negotiations is not the main reason
why the MAI as envisaged will not come about. The main problem
with the MAI is that its negotiators did not expect to have to sell it po-
litically. Most of the MAI negotiators were investment specialists, not
used to viewing from a political perspective the concepts that they con-
1
Editors’ note: A version of this paper was given as evidence to the House of Commons
Environmental Audit Committee Inquiry into the Multilateral Agreement on Investment.
See Multilateral Agreement on Investment, House of Commons Environmental Audit
Committee 1st Report, HC 58, V. II, pp 103–7, January 1999. For an alternative account of
the MAI negotions see David Henderson, The MAI Affair: A Story and its Lessons, RIIA,
London, 1999.
Lessons from the MAI: a view from the negotiating table 243
These three basic themes were retained in the ensuing debates, which
led to the so-called ‘three anchor’ approach of the environment in the
MAI. The first anchor would be the preamble, which should re-affirm
parties’ commitment to the relevant principles of the Rio Declaration
246 Jan Huner
2
Editors’ note: A process to review the Guidelines is currently under way.
Lessons from the MAI: a view from the negotiating table 247
There were also signals from the French that it would be difficult for
them to sell the MAI politically. The artistic and intellectual community
had discovered the MAI as yet another American-inspired instrument
of ultra-liberalism, posing a threat to artistic and literary freedom and
cultural diversity in France. Environment is not the main political con-
cern in France when it comes to investment agreements.
The Chairman of the Negotiating Group made a final attempt in
March to bridge the gap by proposing a package of provisions on
labour and the environment. He did not succeed. Although there was
praise all round for this credible effort, the Europeans saw too many
NAFTA-inspired texts, and the Americans opposed making the ‘not
lowering of standards’ clause binding.
At the OECD ministerial meeting in April 1998, France proposed
that the negotiations be suspended for six months in order to determine
the political viability of MAI. This suited the United States very well,
and it was thus agreed. On 14 October 1998 Prime Minister Jospin
resolutely delivered the final blow to the MAI by announcing that
France had decided to withdraw from the negotiations.
The lessons
At this point, just two weeks after a French torpedo caused the capsiz-
ing of the leaky MAI boat, it is too early to tell precisely what made this
ship so vulnerable. It would be wrong to blame only the French for
sinking it. The truth is that the MAI had become a liability rather than
an asset to most OECD countries, but few countries were willing to
admit it. And it was not just poor handling of the environmental ques-
tion that was the main cause.
Let me offer some personal thoughts on what, in hindsight, caused the
problems. First of all, I remain convinced that the OECD is the right forum
for negotiating an investment agreement. Not only does it have the exper-
tise and the experience in this area, but more importantly, it is an interdis-
ciplinary organization where all other policy areas that were relevant in
the MAI debate are represented. In that sense the OECD is unique.
The question is: did we use this to our advantage? My answer is:
only very modestly, and far too late. Other committees and Secretariat
250 Jan Huner
The immediate start of negotiations [on an MAI] which will provide a broad
multilateral frame-work for international investment with high standards
for the liberalization of investment regimes and investment protection and
with effective dispute settlement procedures.
OECD ministers aimed to replace the vast network of more than 1,600
bilateral investment treaties (BITs) with a multilateral treaty that was
supposed to grant no less protection to foreign investors than the BITs.
BITs generally guarantee national treatment, non-discrimination and
most favoured nation status for foreign investors. Many provide not
only for state–state but also for investor–state dispute resolution. What
is new in the MAI is the element of ‘multilateralization’ and the aim of
significant up-front liberalization. It was not intended to include other
policy objectives in the MAI.
It has thus always been the position of international business that the
MAI is to be an investment agreement – a place to set high standards
for the treatment and protection of investment. An MAI should not and
Lessons from the MAI: an industry view 253
nation treatment). We believe these provisions will ensure that the context
in which countries liberalize investment regimes and develop investor pro-
tection will be consistent with the existing trends toward comprehensive,
effective and science-based environmental standards.
Conclusions
In conclusion, let me quote the diplomatic language used by the UK Min-
ister for Trade, Brian Wilson, last week after the OECD meeting in Paris:
The intention of the MAI negotiating parties had been to present an agree-
ment to OECD ministers for signature in May 1999. This now looks most
unlikely. However, the Government – together with our new partners – re-
mains committed in the longer term to promoting the negotiations on in-
vestment to the WTO.1
1
‘Brian Wilson Voices Support for New Rules on Investment’, DTI Press Release P/98/
799, 21 October 1998.
258 Kristian Ehinger
1. In 1987, after synthetic Nylon 6,6 technology had lost out to steel
radials in the West, E.I. Du Pont de Nemours, the largest chemical
multinational in the United States, decided to shift their outdated
1938-fabricated nylon plant to Goa, a province in western India, in
partnership with an Indian company. Contrary to the firm’s claim of
being safe and clean:
• the production technology is unknown, and the process uses
hexamethylene diamine and adipic acid, which are flammable,
toxic and may be carcinogenic;
• the mandatory Environmental Impact Assessment was not con-
ducted;
1
Editors’ note: In 1991, an internal memorandum from Mr Summers was sent to senior
staff at the World Bank. One passage infamously asked ‘Just between you and me,
shouldn’t the Bank be encouraging more migration of the dirty industries to the LDCs [less
developed countries]? … the economic logic behind dumping a load of toxic waste in the
lowest-wage country is impeccable.’ The Bank apologized on behalf of Mr Summers, who
explained that the comments were intended as an ironic attempt to stimulate policy debate.
See ‘Save Planet Earth from Economists’, Financial Times, 10 February 1992.
Lessons from the MAI: a view from the South 261
of toxic waste between 1972 and 1989.2 Between 1982 and 1992,
Shell’s subsidiary in Nigeria spilled about 1.6 million gallons of oil in
the Niger Delta, most from leaking pipelines, causing high levels of
water pollution and the death of fish, mangroves and tropical forests. In
a blatant example of the application of double standards, Greenpeace
reported that the construction of a single pipeline in Scotland required
Shell to produce 17 environmental surveys and a comprehensive envi-
ronmental impact assessment.
Similar problems have been observed and catalogued in other major
extractive industries such as forestry, mining and fisheries. How far
these problems can be resolved through environmental protection mea-
sures incorporated in an investment agreement is a moot point. Would
such measures lead to investors becoming more benign towards natural
resources and the ecology? Or should the problem not be addressed
through a raft of policy tools, including promotion of sustainable con-
sumption and production? Much work on this issue is currently under
way at the United Nations Commission on Sustainable Development
(CSD).
2
Ian A. Bowles et al., ‘Oil and Gas Development in the Tropical Andes’, in Natural
Resource Extraction in the Latin American Tropics (citing work by Acción Ecológica and
the Natural Resources Defence Council), Conservation International Policy Brief no. 1,
Spring 1998.
Lessons from the MAI: a view from the South 263
There are several other relevant principles, and many are incorporated
in a number of voluntary guidelines, such as the OECD Guidelines for
Multinational Enterprises or the International Chamber of Commerce’s
Business Charter for Sustainable Development.
One of the arguments in favour of incorporating these principles in
an international investment agreement is that it will lead to the contract-
ing parties’ abiding by them through implementation and enforcement
of high standards, without running in a race to the bottom.
1. While the main goal of the MAI was to protect investments from
expropriation and nationalization, and if such an event took place
to provide for quick redress and compensation, its target was the
resources and the consumer markets of developing countries who
were never even a part of the negotiations.
2. The United States, at the instigation of its big business lobbies,
pushed the developed world to launch negotiations on the MAI in
early 1995 in the OECD, even though a multilateral forum for trade,
the World Trade Organization, had just been established.
264 Pradeep S. Mehta
there are powerful reasons to have the matter dropped altogether from the
WTO agenda. First, the WTO is now a ‘Single undertaking’ so that the re-
vised MAI would still be mandatory on all WTO members. The issues it
touches are inherently controversial, will take the WTO gratuitously into
the politically supercharged domain, and endanger its real mission: to free
trade.
Many of us have been arguing that labour and environmental agendas be
pursued (proactively) by means other than trade treaties and institutions,
leaving the WTO to pursue free trade instead. But it is hard to tell the lob-
bies seeking to push these agendas into the WTO to get off its back even as
the MAI is sought to be worked into the WTO. It was bad enough to work
Intellectual Property Protection – an issue of enforcement of asserted prop-
erty rights against essentially poor nations rather than of trade where all
gain – into the WTO as the Uruguay Round closed. But with intellectual
property protection and an MAI both in, it would be hard to refute the
charge that what is good for capital at the WTO is not good for labour or for
nature.
268 Pradeep S. Mehta
Conclusion
In conclusion, there are three key questions to be considered:
Introduction
The World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF) has worked on the MAI since
June 1996. We have produced between 12 and 14 papers and we have
had the dubious honour of being both praised and dismissed by sitting
ministers of state in the United Kingdom, though the government of
course retains a firm, united front on the issue!
The MAI has changed the intellectual and political climate for de-
bate on macroeconomic policy. This is partly because the negotia-
tions spanned the financial crisis, the causes of which were deeply
entwined with some of the capital liberalization issues in the MAI and
the IMF. Liberalization can never again be considered in isolation from
other issues. The idea that the sanctity of the WTO, or of any body that
deals with economics, can be preserved while environmental or other
issues are addressed in another forum is never going to become reality.
Investment affects everything and it is much more invasive than trade.
This was not appreciated by the MAI negotiators when they started.
Civil society and other government departments can no longer be ex-
cluded. It is no longer acceptable to try to bounce developing countries
into an agreement they have not negotiated. This was the biggest point
of principle against the MAI. When WWF started lobbying on the MAI
we were told it was not about developing countries, and just before it
collapsed the head of OECD said it was for developing countries. That
kind of volte face spreads distrust and undermines both the UN system
and the trust between North and South that we need if we are to move
forward.
As to an ‘Environment Investment Agreement’, if you look at the
European Union and its environmental harmonization, there is a pretty
strong case that has to be disproved by the other side for why environ-
ment should not be considered integrally inside an investment agree-
ment.
270 Nick Mabey
If you take this view of the world, the only environmental problem
you come up with is the game theorist’s ‘prisoner’s dilemma’: that
countries will outbid each other by lowering standards over labour and
environment in order to attract investment, and that this is ‘non-opti-
mal’. This is why there is the ‘no lowering of standards’ clause in the
MAI; it flows directly from that logic. So the policy recommendations
are to raise domestic standards and coordinate action on incentives. If
you take this view of the world, you end up thinking that the MAI is a
very bland agreement: it does not really do a lot; it is ‘just’ an invest-
ment architecture, and you simply have to fiddle at the edges to deal
with other issues.
This ‘first-best policy’ perspective does not even approach the reali-
ties of liberalization. It is intellectually dishonest and factually incor-
rect. Show me a first-best world, and I will give you a first-best policy.
But the assumptions of the model that underlie the MAI are false and
they will always be false. This is where the tension arises.
since 95 per cent of investment comes from OECD countries – the ones
who are negotiating the agreement.
In this world, there are some new rules that go beyond the old-world
aim of capital efficiency. There is uncertainty and irreversible environ-
mental and social damage which is coded in the precautionary prin-
ciple – a key principle left out of the MAI. There is also the question of
equity: who suffers damage, and who gets benefits? If you trade envi-
ronmental quality against getting a factory built, or a resource-using
investment made, it is usually the same people who do not benefit from
the economic growth who suffer the environmental damage. The ‘pol-
luter pays’ principle was another principle from Rio that was left out of
an OECD agreement, although in many ways it is the OECD’s prin-
ciple. The issues of equity and compensation have to be addressed. It
is interesting that, compared with the deal-making culture of the WTO,
environmental agreements are about assigning responsibility and not
about doing deals – which is much harder for countries to accept.
If you consider that a country like the UK has been responsible for a
vastly disproportionate amount of emissions of CO2 over its lifetime as
a country (given that we industrialized first), you can see that we owe a
debt to the rest of the world, because our pollution has formed the
foundation of our capital stock and our current wealth. So environmen-
tal agreements are very bound up, in the new world, with distribution
of resources and equal access to the global commons. These are con-
cepts that are completely missing from the ‘efficient’ world of the MAI.
The rights of non-state actors were codified at the Rio Earth Summit.
People have the right to be heard independently of their nation-state;
they have the right to have some access. This was not addressed in the
MAI. The whole complex area of the indirect impacts of investment –
migration, urbanization, changes in structures, breakdown of social
groups, leading in turn to more environmental damage – was not even
on the agenda in the MAI. That is the world in which most of us are
working and how we see the impact of investment.
There are ecological limits to what we do and there are human rights
limits to what we do, and these cannot be traded off against economic
growth. There are limits to trade-offs and these limits are made up of
environmental, political and cultural rights. In this complex, contin-
Lessons from the MAI: an NGO view 273
gent and difficult world you have to consider every case and see what
happens when you open up markets and let investors in. Does it in-
crease development, does it reduce poverty, does it hurt the environ-
ment? This is not a case for promoting protectionism: it is a case for a
little more reality, a little less high-level assumptions and a little more
looking at what is really going on, including giving governments the
capacity to see what is going on.
International investment frameworks must enable environmental
protection. They are not a panacea. We never said we wanted to cure
the world’s environmental problems with the MAI, though this was
yet another caricature of the environmental groups’ position. We just
wanted to make sure that the MAI supported the efforts we are all pur-
suing at national and subnational levels. But it did not: it stopped them;
it chilled them. As well as not producing a positive agenda, the MAI
limited our ability to go down a positive road. Performance require-
ments, for example, can affect recycling, technology transfer, local
community management – all the projects WWF undertakes abroad.
They can prevent the capturing of resource rents, thereby reducing in-
centives for sustainable management.
Subsidiarity
It really comes down to the subsidiarity principle. The MAI was in
favour of investor protection. But investor protection was not an issue
for any company I talked to during the negotiations. The agenda of
investor protection is an old agenda, and I do not believe that people
have seen it as a major agenda since the 1970s. The MAI was in favour
of liberalization. But countries are liberalizing anyway, and in the stud-
ies that we have looked at, and in the countries we have visited, it does
not appear that liberalization is connected to capital flows. The MAI
was the wrong place to push liberalization. Liberalization and the
opening of markets should be decided by national actors. National ac-
tors may want to make sure that someone else cannot reverse these
decisions later to gain credibility, but that is very different from having
an instrument that sees rolling back regulation, and rolling back barri-
ers, as its main aim.
274 Nick Mabey
The MAI was clearly a very bad piece of economic policy. But
where do we go from here? If you want a new objective, then that ob-
jective is sustainable development. WWF has many ideas as to how
that could be promoted inside investment agreements. These include
requirements for environmental assessment, and a code of conduct
linked to investor protection so that you get protection from the inter-
national system only if you follow the international system’s rules.
That is pretty reasonable, and it happens in national countries. Liability
should flow with profits back to the home country: that is an important
principle, a remedy of last resort but something we would like. There
should be more emphasis on the positives: supporting ethical business,
supporting good-practice businesses by giving them preferential ac-
cess to guaranteed loans and trade promotion. Let us give people out
there a carrot to move in the right direction. We are not interested in
dealing with a bad agreement; we want to deal with a good agreement.
In conclusion, the areas we need agreement on generally cover the
things that weren’t in the MAI. I am not sure that the MAI had any eco-
nomic use at all, apart from increasing the bargaining power of incom-
ing investors. Politically, rights and responsibilities have to be linked
together, because you cannot get rules on responsibility for companies
without giving them something in return. WWF can work on some cre-
ative institutional lobbying in some different institutions, but the poli-
tics do not allow us to move in entirely separate and unconnected
tracks. If investment is simply passed over to the WTO and there is no
fundamental rethink, there will just be NGO opposition again. NGOs
want to see some thinking about objectives and some thinking about
how people negotiate.
Finally, my favourite quote from a leader in The Financial Times:
‘One lesson for international negotiations from the MAI fiasco – this is
not how to do it!’
Part V
Summary of conference discussions
Halina Ward
Introduction
This section contains a short overview of the discussions that followed
each of the presentations at the Chatham House conference on ‘Trade,
Investment and the Environment’ in October 1998. The conference it-
self was attended by some 150 people, an international mix drawn
from government, industry, international institutions, non-governmen-
tal organizations and the academic world. Chatham House was par-
ticularly pleased that sponsorship made possible the participation of a
number of developing-country experts who would not otherwise have
been able to attend.
The discussion sections of the conference clearly reflected the high
level of expertise in the audience, and a search for ‘solutions’ rather
than a simple exploration of the issues. For the most part, the discus-
sion was ‘on the record’. Here, however, the aim is to present some of
the key themes and ideas, without identifying individual questioners.
The summaries of presentations are my own, and have not been re-
viewed by their authors. The structure of the original conference is re-
tained.
Day one
Brian Wilson MP, UK Minister for Trade, opened the conference with a
keynote address (see Part I). The opportunity to question a trade minis-
ter on environment and development issues was clearly welcomed by
many. What could be done to ensure that the proposed WTO High
Level Meeting was different from discussions in the Committee on
Trade and Environment (CTE), which had helped to air many of the
issues, but had not reached consensus? And, in the light of the lack of
developing country participation in the MAI, could redefining the ob-
jectives of investment liberalization help to build consensus among
less developed countries, and between developed and developing
280 Halina Ward
required to meet their requirements, and the idea that they could be a
distraction from another ‘good’, namely active corporate disclosure.
He underlined the potential business benefits of an approach based
on a policy of ‘active engagement’ with external stakeholders, but ar-
gued that labelling schemes themselves were unlikely to lead to much
progress. What was needed from policy-makers was more mandated
corporate disclosure (including possibly environmental or social dis-
closure attached to stock exchange listing requirements), and manda-
tory labelling on crucial environmental and social issues. In discussion,
one speaker countered with a note of caution on mandatory certification
and labelling – it could simply lead to control being handed over from
producers (e.g. farmers in the case of organic certification) to bureau-
crats. An alternative approach to the problem of ‘label proliferation’
was raised in discussion: if too many labels in the marketplace simply
confuse consumers, why not seek to develop international standards?
with at the most appropriate level, and that some issues call for a glo-
bal governance system. On the other hand, Mr Gummer stressed that
subsidiarity should be seen as a ‘bottom-up’ concept. From a top-
down perspective, subsidiarity ‘always stops at your level’. Calling for
a global governance structure could be going too far. But for many
participants, what was needed was an equally powerful body along-
side the WTO on the side of environment and, more than that, sustain-
able development. The cultural dimension of trade also needed atten-
tion – i.e. protecting the ‘biodiversity of humanity’. Yet here, one
man’s culture could be another man’s protectionism.
Day two
Session 3: Environment and investment
Session 3 opened with a focus on investment and the role of trans-
national corporations. To what extent could the activities of private
actors improve environmental standards? Do transnational corpora-
tions ‘leapfrog’ environmentally sound technologies to the developing
world or outsource dirty technologies? Can environmental regulation
be ‘win–win’? What role can or should transnational corporations play
in multilateral negotiations? Three speakers addressed these and re-
lated issues: Tom Burke (see Part I), Veena Jha, with a particular focus
on the experience in India (see Part II); and David Owen, with a par-
ticular focus on the water sector (Part IV).
For NGOs, a key issue in the discussion session was the links between
deregulation and a move towards enhanced private-sector power. One
participant put forward some minimum preconditions that would need
to be met before her organization could accept that activities of trans-
national corporations could lead to improved environmental standards:
these included recognition of the development priorities of host coun-
tries; acceptance of community and national ownership of natural re-
sources; acceptance of labour and human rights; and a recognition that
resources are finite.
Still on the NGO side, one participant said that it was becoming clear
from a strategic perspective that NGOs would need to consider more
closely the role of transnational corporations in international negotia-
286 Halina Ward
tions. One related area for consideration was the hypothesis that it was
in the interests of transnational corporations to promote the creation of
a forum in which trade and environment could be integrated, given
their interest in the convergence of the two regimes. An obstacle lies
not so much with companies as with a lack of political will to deliver
up the sovereignty necessary to create a global environment organiza-
tion. The WTO is as powerful as it is precisely because it has been ac-
companied by a transfer of sovereignty of a scale that would not be
feasible on the environment side.
What of the related possibility of some degree of convergence be-
tween ‘government’ and ‘public’ politics, for example over GMOs?
How could this impact on transnational corporations? Such conver-
gence around future conflict over GMOs might not prove to be on
terms sought by corporate elites. There is a real danger, said one spea-
ker, that both the economy and the environment could be undermined
precisely because of the enormous lack of integration between them.
arisen in the Beef Hormones case, when the Appellate Body changed
the burden of proof, but wasn’t able to send the case back to be heard
again through this new lense. Finally, he suggested that perhaps an of-
ficial voice to represent the WTO Secretariat in dispute settlement pro-
ceedings could be a useful idea.
ated: beyond trade and trade-related aspects, the WTO should not be
made an organization that looks at different interests from labour to
good governance. But participants were also reminded of the ‘chill
factor’ that could result from a failure properly to integrate trade and
environment, or, as a result, from trade officials becoming involved in
international environmental negotiations.
There was criticism of the Committee on Trade and Environment.
Had it gone far enough or even outlived its usefulness? In some areas
perhaps, one participant suggested, the CTE had already done as much
work as it could be expected to do. If this work had not delivered a
‘solution’, perhaps that was because there was nowhere to go on these
issues.
Could the Millennium Round prove to be the ‘terminal round’ for the
WTO? Could a failure sufficiently to accommodate environment and
sustainable development concerns lead to its demise? Or does it in re-
ality work rather well? One participant emphasized that, for example,
in terms of all the requests for consultations initiated under the WTO,
only a very small number had anything to do with environment.
Discussion returned to the ‘win–win’ theme and its implications. For
one speaker, there was a need to focus more on the dynamics of trade
in the marketplace – on the dialectic between companies in their sup-
ply chains and associated policy moves, not simply on the dialectic
between ‘unilateral’ and ‘multilateral’. As to the implications of ‘win–
win’ solutions for the Millennium Round, one government participant
highlighted three areas ‘ripe for the picking’ in terms of win–win solu-
tions: (1) the elimination of fisheries subsidies, an area where consider-
able work had already been done; (2) the General Agreement on Trade
in Services, where there could be a very clear and direct link between
improved market access and environmental gains; and (3) the elimina-
tion of export subsidies in agriculture, to put an end to the current sig-
nals for overproduction, trade distortion and land use with negative
impacts. The conceptual thinking on the ‘win–win’ theme had already
been done. The challenge now was to identify the key areas for re-
form – to enable developing countries to say ‘yes’ to genuinely ‘win–
win’ solutions.
Index
ILO see International Labour labelling 15, 83–7, 156, 223–4, 281–2
Organization see also eco-labelling
imperialism, economic 39–41, 97 Lango Cooperatives Union, Uganda
India 64–5, 214–18, 221–9, 260–1 66
institutional capacity, developing LCA see Life Cycle Analysis
countries 69–70 least developed country needs 8
intellectual property rights (IPRs) liberalization of trade 11–12, 158–9,
178–80, 226–7 228, 230–41, 273, 284
international environmental Life Cycle Analysis (LCA) 14, 84
organization 25, 26, 130, 286, 289 ‘like products’ 125, 193–4, 198
International Institute for Environment ambiguity 176–8
and Development (IIED) 64, 71–2 concept 155–6
International Labour Organization PPMs 177–82
(ILO) 8 see also intellectual property rights
International Organization for
Standardization (ISO) 84–5, 154, Mabey, Nick 269–75
175 MAI see Multilateral Agreement on
14000 series 53, 59, 171–2 Investment
certification 62 market access 114–20, 167–8
TNCs 221, 224–5 market forces 163–4
International Tropical Timber Marrakesh Agreement 103–4, 127
Organization (ITTO) 52, 77 Maruti Udyog 220–1
Internet 8, 207, 245, 247, 251 Mehta, Pradeep S. 259–68, 287
investment Millennium Round 26, 131–4, 136–7,
bilateral investment treaties, 252 290
FDI 168–9, 211–29, 265–6 Moltke, Konrad von 177–82, 283
international 16–17, 78–9, 287 Montreal Protocol 37, 98, 122, 123–4,
see also Multilateral Agreement on 132, 162–3, 282
Investment MTS see multilateral trading system
investor protection 273–4 Multilateral Agreement on Investment
investor-state dispute settlement 242– (MAI) 16–17, 242–51
3, 254–5 background 243–9
ISO see International Organization for developing countries 259–68
Standardization expropriation provisions 248, 254
ITTO see International Tropical failings 102–3, 255–6, 263–5,
Timber Organization 270–3
France 249
Jha, Veena 211–29, 282, 285 globalization 255
India position 225–6
Kyoto Protocol 140, 282 industry position 252–8
Index 295